Preferred Citation: Watson, Rubie S., and Patricia Buckley Ebrey, editors Marriage and Inequality in Chinese Society. Berkeley:  University of California Press,  c1991 1991. http://ark.cdlib.org/ark:/13030/ft6p3007p1/


cover

Marriage and Inequality in Chinese Society

Edited by
Rubie S. Watson
Patricia Buckley Ebrey

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA PRESS
Berkeley · Los Angeles · Oxford
© 1991 The Regents of the University of California


Preferred Citation: Watson, Rubie S., and Patricia Buckley Ebrey, editors Marriage and Inequality in Chinese Society. Berkeley:  University of California Press,  c1991 1991. http://ark.cdlib.org/ark:/13030/ft6p3007p1/


xiii

Preface

In her autobiography, published in 1936, Hsieh Ping-ying described her parents as having traditional attitudes about marriage. They had betrothed her as an infant to the son of a prominent and well-to-do family. Both her father and mother considered the fulfillment of this agreement essential to their family's honor. Her mother took charge of preparing the dowry, using money and materials she had been saving for more than ten years. She supervised workmen who spent several months constructing and lacquering forty pieces of furniture. She had quilts and mosquito nets made. She called in tailors to make clothes for each season. When Ping-ying urged her mother not to have too many dresses made, as styles might change, her mother replied:

To be a bride and not to have many dresses would be looked down upon by others. Many people have to sell their fields and their property to prepare a trousseau for their daughters. When your elder sister's husband's family married off their daughter they had thirty-two silk coverlets and twenty-eight woolen blankets, but I know that they had to sell their rice field to make a show. Although I like to do my best for my daughters, I do not hold that people should really dispose of their property handed down to them by their ancestors in order to be luxurious in the wedding ceremony. If the trousseau is not too modest, that is sufficient. (Hsieh Ping-ying, Autobiography of a Chinese Girl , trans. Tsui Chi [1943; reprint, London: Pandora, 1986], p. 169)

Ten days before the wedding was scheduled, Hsieh Ping-ying's dowry was delivered to the fiancé's home. But the wedding itself never took place because, after three attempts, Ping-ying ran away from her parents' house, where she had been confined under close watch.

This volume is a collaborative effort to explore the social and historical bases of the marriage system that Hsieh Ping-ying's parents took for granted. What logic led to betrothals in infancy? What social or economic realities


xiv

required elaborate dowry preparations? What definitions of honor would lead parents to imprison a daughter rather than allow an engagement to be broken? To explore such questions, we organized the Conference on Marriage and Inequality in Chinese Society held in January 1988 at the Asilomar Conference Center, Pacific Grove, California. We asked a group of historians and social scientists to look beyond the descent paradigm, which has been so dominant in our thinking about Chinese kinship, to discern ways marriage was implicated in the formation of group identities, political and economic networks, mobility strategies, and differentiation by gender. We started with the proposition that marriage is inevitably linked to social and economic hierarchies and that it both structures and is structured by relations of inequality. On the assumption that the links between marriage and other social formations may have varied by class and changed over time, we invited participants with expertise in a wide range of time periods and social groups. As organizers of the conference and editors of the volume, our previous interests in marriage, kinship, and gender relations colored our original charge. We were fortunate to assemble a group of historians and social scientists who both complemented our interests and broadened our horizons.

Taken as a whole the chapters in this volume show that marriage was deeply involved in the exercise and manipulation of political power, in the creation and distribution of prestige, and in the structuring of gender relations. Despite our emphasis on discerning and analyzing change, we found continuities across time striking: from the classical period to the Revolution of 1949 there were similarities in exogamy rules, wedding rituals, and the treatment of women. Yet the authors also present evidence of change in monogamy, divorce, dowry, and symbolic uses of marriage that they relate to alterations in the composition of the elite and the commercialization of the economy. Those familiar with marriage systems elsewhere in Asia and Europe will recognize similarities in the ways honor and property came to be tied to marriage in China. Yet dowry in China, we argue, also had some unique characteristics. Confucian ideology—with its stress on patriliny over matrilateral and affinal ties—combined with legal restrictions on women's claims to property created a dowry complex distinct from the ones found in Europe and India.

The Conference on Marriage and Inequality in Chinese Society was sponsored by the Joint Committee on Chinese Studies of the American Council of Learned Societies and the Social Science Research Council, with funds provided by the Andrew W. Mellon Foundation. We are indebted to them for their support. We also acknowledge with gratitude the participation of scholars not represented in this volume: Beverly Bossler, Myron Cohen, Jerry Dennerline, Jack Goody, Dennis Grafflin, Diane Hughes, Cho-yun Hsu, Susan Naquin, Janice Stockard, Martin Whyte, and Arthur Wolf. The general arguments presented in the Introduction and Afterword, as well as


xv

the shape of individual chapters, owe much to their analyses and critiques during four days of intense discussion at Asilomar. We are also grateful to Stevan Harrell, who took time from a busy schedule to read the final manuscript with care and provide us with constructive criticism. The Asian Studies Program of the University of Pittsburgh and the Center for East Asian and Pacific Studies at the University of Illinois assisted in organizing the conference and in preparing the manuscript. We are pleased to acknowledge this help.

RSW
PBE


xvii

Chronology of Chinese History

Classical period

Chou dynasty, ca. 1000-256 B.C.

Western Chou, ca. 1000-771 B.C.

Eastern Chou, 770-256 B.C.

Spring and Autumn period, 770-453 B.C.

Warring States period, 453-256 B.C.

Imperial period, 221 B.C.-A.D. 1911

 

Major native Chinese dynasties

Major non-Han dynasties

Ch'in, 221-206 B.C.

 

Former Han, 206 B.C.-A.D. 9

 

Later Han, 25-220

 

Southern dynasties, 317-589

Northern dynasties, 386-581

Northern Wei (T'o-pa), 399-534

T'ang 617-907

 
 

Liao (Ch'i-tan), 916-1122

Sung, 960-1279

Chin (Jurchen), 1115-1234

Yuan (Mongol), 1260-1368

Ming, 1368-1664

 
 

Ch'ing (Manchu), 1644-1911

Republic, 1911-1949

 

People's Republic, 1949-present

 

1

Introduction

Patricia Buckley Ebrey

Inequalities of many sorts characterized Chinese society. During the imperial period, the emperor outranked all of his subjects. Members of the imperial family and clan possessed titles, rank, privileges, and stipends that distinguished them from the rest of society. Government officials were set above commoners by their access to wealth and power and enormous social prestige. Crosscutting these political inequalities were social, economic, and geographic ones. Merchants and large landowners could dominate their communities through their control of resources; educated families of established reputations could expect deference based on their culture, history, manners, and style; residents of cities in economically developed areas had social, economic, and even political advantages over rural residents in the hinterlands. And throughout society, from the imperial court to the peasant household, men outranked women. In the twentieth century traditional political inequalities lost their legal force, and after 1949 most of the old sources of economic inequality, especially the private ownership of land, were eliminated. In addition, the state promoted greater legal equality of men and women in matters of marriage and property ownership. Yet in the second half of the twentieth century new sources of inequality emerged, such as class labels, party membership, and city residence.

The authors of this book examine the relation between marriage and these social, political, and economic inequalities. Inequality has not been a neglected topic in Chinese studies. The imperial institution, the civil service recruitment system, the distribution of landholding, and the ideology of class and gender differentiation have all been studied in detail. Little research has been devoted, however, to the mechanisms or processes through which inequalities were reproduced or transformed over time. Marriage also is not a neglected topic. Anthropological and sociological studies of China generally


2

include some discussion of marriage, and several studies analyze marriage practices and affinity in detail (e.g., Kulp 1925, Lang 1946, Hsu 1948, Gallin 1960, M. Wolf 1972, Ahern 1974, Cohen 1976, Freedman 1979, A. Wolf and Huang 1980, Watson 1981, Croll 1981). Yet little attention has been given to the ways marriage mediated inequality or inequalities structured marriage. In this volume we investigate these processes and mechanisms by focusing on how marriage relates to three forms of inequality: the political power of rulers; the social and economic differences among families; and the inequalities between men and women and among women. Because our goal is to discover the broad outlines of these processes, we examine marriage in a wide range of social settings from very early to very recent times.

Marriage and Inequality

Before introducing the chapters in this volume, we must place our discussion in a broad theoretical and comparative framework. Whenever a marriage takes place, the standing of every party is somewhat different from what it had been. Almost invariably at least one person, the husband or wife, changes residence. In many cases control over wealth changes hands. In China, where most of the family estate was transmitted to patrilineal descendants, it was fairly common for some property to be diverted to daughters as dowries. Marriages regularly allocate privileges, claims, and obligations, usually in different ways for men and women. In the Chinese case, in a patrilocal marriage the husband gained sexual access to his wife and his patriline gained claims to her labor and the children she would bear. But the wife also gained privileges through marriage, such as the claim to maintenance on her husband's estate and a place of honor in ancestral rites. Marriages everywhere confer honor: individual men and women become recognized adults by marrying; at the same time families gain in standing by marrying their children respectably. In most societies weddings are great occasions for displaying status; sometimes more is spent on the ritual festivities than on the durable items that end up in the dowry as families perform the rites elaborately to confirm or enhance their status.

Viewed from the perspective of the individual family, every marriage provides a chance to gain or lose economically or socially. Marriages are thus occasions for thinking tactically, for balancing many considerations. A family head need not make similar matches for each daughter; in one case he may seek useful affines, in another emphasize the financial considerations, in a third think first of his daughter's welfare. Marriage choices can be compared to market choices, with the various decision makers weighing an assortment of factors, including the age and attractiveness of their children, the supply of potential spouses, other demands on their resources, and so on. In the Chinese context the flexibility of marriage decisions stands in contrast to


3

inheritance and succession, where choices were few and preferences clear. Because property had to be divided among all sons, parents had little leeway to manipulate in favor of one heir or another.

Viewed from the larger society, however, the range of possibilities open for each match fades. Certain types of marriage systems structure the ways wealth, power, and status are distributed in the society from one family to another and from one generation to another and the ways rights, privileges, and honor are assigned differentially to men and women. Jack Goody has developed the most influential model of the structural consequences of systems of marriage exchange. In "Bridewealth and Dowry in Africa and Eurasia" (1973) Goody distinguishes between those societies that transmit property through daughters via dowry or inheritance (including to some degree most of the state-based societies of Eurasia) and those that do not (notably the bridewealth societies of Africa). He argues that societies with "diverging devolution" (the same types of property passing through both men and women whether through inheritance or dowry) are marked by monogamy, family control of daughters' marriages, emphasis on virginity, strong ties between affines, greater class distinctions, and stronger women's property rights (a set of characteristics I shall refer to here as the "dowry complex"). Goody shows many logical links between these characteristics. Where families send their daughters with dowries, Goody explains, they do not want misalliances and cannot risk letting daughters choose on the basis of attraction. When marriages require matching property, property stays disproportionately in the upper classes, and class inequalities are thereby strengthened. Families providing portions for a daughter want some guarantee that the property will be used to her benefit, especially if she is widowed (1973:17-47). In some societies (like China) daughters did not regularly receive family property but could be residual heirs, that is, allowed to transmit the family property through uxorilocal marriages when there were no sons; these, too, Goody classes as societies practicing diverging devolution (1976a:10-36). In Production and Reproduction (1976b) Goody adds a developmental dimension to this model, linking diverging devolution to the introduction of the animal-drawn plow and the greater economic surplus it allowed. Diverging devolution is thus also related to greater social and economic differentiation and the development of states. In this book he also analyzes concubinage and the inequality in the household created by an unbalanced marriage exchange (i.e., the purchase of concubines, who, unlike wives, do not bring dowries). In The Development of Family and Marriage in Europe (1983) Goody brings these conceptions to bear on the complex historical changes in Western history from the Roman Empire to early modern times, showing that marriage forms do not flow automatically from economic structures but are complexly tied to dominant institutions and ideologies. Goody's analyses, taken together, provide a new way to think about the linkage of gender and


4

kinship. Goody's studies do not show women relegated to a domestic sphere defined by the biology of motherhood, while men operate in a public sphere shaped by the political economy and the forces of history. To the contrary, he describes a domestic domain shaped by productive processes and the transmission of property (see Collier and Yanagisako 1987:4-6).

Goody's work on marriage has been utilized by several China scholars (Parish and Whyte 1978; Ebrey 1981, 1986; Watson 1984; Holmgren 1985). His model provides an alternative to full reliance on the lineage model of Chinese kinship, which makes patrilineal kinship so central that transmission of property through women in uxorilocal marriage or via dowries appears to be a peripheral embellishment of little structural importance (cf. Freedman 1958; Baker 1979). Yet there are obstacles to wholesale acceptance of Goody's model: the relative weakness of women's legal claims to property in China; the fact that many, maybe even a majority, of marriages did not involve significant transfers from the bride's side; and the difficulty in characterizing China as either a dowry or a bridewealth society as both coexisted (e.g., McCreery 1976). Moreover, it is not clear that a model designed to explain the broadest differences between dissimilar societies can also provide insight into the narrower differences that China scholars seek to understand, such as why dowry was more prominent in India than in China, or why dowries were more substantial in some parts of China than in others. In some areas of north and central China, peasants are reported to have spent considerable sums on dowries (Fei 1939:44; Yang 1945:79, 110, 113; Gamble 1954:383; Cohen 1988). In the south, especially in areas with dominant lineages, dowries among the poor were often modest affairs, costing the woman's family significantly less than the amount they received in betrothal girls (see Kulp 1925:173-75; Watson 1981). Do differences in kinship organization or agricultural methods explain these differences? Did women in areas with large dowries have higher status than those in areas without them?

Goody's theories do not place much weight on ritual and the display of status through marriage and have been criticized as being overly "econo-centric" (see Comaroff 1980; Harrell and Dickey 1985). Other anthropologists have delved more deeply into the symbolic dimensions of marriage exchanges and the ways they establish and restructure the relations of all the parties concerned (wife-givers and wife-takers, but also husbands and wives, or husbands' families and daughters-in-law). The benefits that flow from a marriage are not all tangible or clearly specified. In the classic study of gift giving, the French sociologist Marcel Mauss argues that gifts create an imbalance between the giver and the receiver. The recipient is indebted to the giver until the gift is repaid, at which time the debt is canceled or, if the return gift exceeds the initial gift, a new state of imbalance is established (1966). Basing their analyses on Mauss's work, many anthropologists argue


5

that the transfer of goods at marriage maintains economic and political differences by confirming them. Bourdieu, for instance, writes that marriage was "one of the mainstays of both the dynamic and the static elements of the entire social system" to the extent that it afforded the families he studied "one of the most important opportunities for monetary and also symbolic exchanges that asserted the family's position in the social hierarchy and thereby confirmed that hierarchy itself" (1976:124). Marriage, in effect, becomes part of the system of social reproduction in which status, rank, and class differences are passed on to the next generation. Marriage exchange, after all, involves not only the giving and receiving of land, money, and jewelry but also the offering of words, bows, and other "gifts" of respect. Sometimes the potential for expression of status is not equal in all forms of marriage. In China it is generally thought that only "major" marriages (patrilocal marriages of mature brides) could be used to full advantage in the display and celebration of high status (cf. Fei 1939:54-55; Freedman 1957:65).

Where marriages regularly join families of unequal rank, the relationship of marriage to inequality differs from the cases discussed above. Hypergamy (women marrying up) or hypogamy (women marrying down) creates patterns of social inequality based on prestige or rank, families confirming or enhancing their status by the partners they pick and often subsidizing families of higher rank by providing dowries (Leach 1954; Dumont 1957; Inden 1976; Parry 1979). These patterns sometimes create a visible pecking order, for the families to whom one sends daughters will never be the same ones from whom one receives brides. It has often been suggested that Chinese society tends toward hypergamy (see Ahern 1974; Freedman 1979), but the degree of status differences and the relative incidence of hypergamous marriages have never been adequately studied. A tendency toward hypergamy does seem plausible, however, given the asymmetry inherent in a patrilineal, patrilocal system. After marriage, a woman's status will largely be determined by the social and economic standing of the family she has joined, and so she will gain by marriage "up" into a prosperous family. By contrast, the welfare of the groom and his family is less affected by the family origins of the new daughter-in-law, so they have little to lose by taking a bride from a family of less wealth or social standing. Such brides had attractions; in fact, they were thought to be harder workers and more easily satisfied with their situations.[1]

In Goody's model, transmitting property through women is linked to strong social ties among affines. Indeed, in China and elsewhere marriages are often considered opportunities to make new allies. In the Chinese case, however, affines were not invariably considered useful; they could also prove burdensome or meddlesome. Within the Chinese repertoire of kinship practices, close or distant ties to affines were both well-established possi-


6

bilities (see Gallin and Gallin 1985). For instance, in the dominant lineages of Kwangtung, the rich and the poor seem to have followed different strategies. The rich put great emphasis on strong ties to affines, gave handsome dowries, and married with families some distance away. The poor neither gave dowries nor made any efforts to maintain extensive ties to wives' or mothers' families (Watson 1981). In Taiwan, the value placed on affinity seems to have varied with the form of agriculture; where cooperation was needed for temporary agricultural labor or political assistance, affinal kinship tended to be strongest (Pasternak 1972:60-67).

From the work of European historians, we know that marriage also relates to inequality by means of succession and inheritance. In societies where only those born into fully legal marriages could succeed to thrones, fiefs, or estates, marriage was a crucial mechanism in the transmission of power. The authority to determine what constituted a legal marriage consequently became a source of contention between the church and civil authorities (e.g., Duby 1978). Thus, ritual and ideology need not merely highlight inequalities or obfuscate transactions: the power to define marriage can have great consequence for individuals' social status and inheritance. In the Chinese case, from early imperial times there were laws that defined a legal marriage (as opposed to common-law marriage or concubinage). Yet the legal status of a marriage did not determine the status of heirs, who could inherit at their father's will (Freedman 1979:118; Watson 1985:105-16). Ruling families are the exception to this generalization, for only one son could succeed to a throne or fief, and the status of their mothers' marriages was usually a key issue in deciding which of several sons succeeded, making the link between marriage and the status of offspring different from that in other families.

Placing the Chinese case in comparative perspective raises several key questions that the authors of this volume pursue. Did anything resembling a "dowry complex" develop in China? How significant were hypergamy or hypogamy? Did the symbolism and the tangible benefits of marriage exchanges reinforce or mask the inequalities between wife-givers and wife-takers and men and women? Did forms of marriage differ when succession to a fief or office was at stake?

Collaboration

Our current knowledge of Chinese marriage is based largely on observations made during the last century by social scientists. Given the many continuities in Chinese marriage practices, these studies provide considerable insight into earlier periods. Yet they are no substitute for historical research. We have as a consequence tried to remain open to the possibility that marriage institutions changed in some fundamental ways from early to modern times, as they did in the West. The historians writing here have had to decide


7

how well the terms and concepts commonly used by anthropologists convey what they know of past societies. Although no set of terms is fully adequate, a common vocabulary aids communication among ourselves and with scholars of other societies. In this book we use key terms in the Following ways:

wife . "Wife" seems a fully adequate translation of ch'i and any terms the Ghinese considered a synonym for ch'i (such as shih, shih-jen ) or a polite title for ch'i (such as fu-jen ).

secondary wife . In the preimperial period aristocratic marriages often involved a principal wife bringing with her one or more younger women from her own or related lineages who could also serve as mates of her husband. These women, called ying in Ghinese, are referred to here as secondary wives.

concubine . "Concubine" is used as a translation of ch'ieh and words used as alternatives for ch'ieh , such as hou-shih and ts'e-shih . We prefer it to "secondary wife" not merely to avoid confusion with the ancient practice described above but also because Ghina from Han times on was legally monogamous—a man could have only one wife.

second wife . If a man remarried after the death or divorce of his first wife, his new wife is a second wife. From Han times on, she was usually called a chi-shih , or "successor wife" (or successor "room").

betrothal gifts/brideprice/bridewealth . Gifts (including money) presented by the groom's family to the bride's to seal the betrothal, no matter what their value, are referred to here by these terms, the choice depending on the context and the preferences of the authors. "Betrothal gifts" is a translation of the Chinese terms na-ts'ai, p'in-ts'ai, p'in-li, li-chin, p'in-chin , and other synonyms and as such avoids some of the difficulties of the common terms "brideprice" and "bridewealth." In contrast to the classic bridewealth systems of Africa, in China the money or goods received by the bride's family were often used to prepare her dowry.

dowry . We are labeling any material possession the bride brought with her into marriage, no matter how meager, her dowry. This could include clothes, jewelry, bedding, money, land, and so on. Chinese terms with much the same meaning are chuang-lien, chia-chuang, tzu-sung, tzu-chuang , and so on. Some authors here also use the term "trousseau" to refer to the part of a bride's dowry consisting of her clothes, jewelry, and cosmetics. Labeling something "dowry" is not meant to imply anything about the claims various parties had to its use or disposal, which are instead treated as subjects for research.

indirect dowry . When the bride's family used the betrothal gifts it received to prepare the dowry, the gifts from the man's family that eventually became dowry can be referred to as indirect dowry. This designation


8

places emphasis on the final destination of the property, rather than the initial phase of the flow, and is useful in analyzing the transfer of property over time. It should be remembered, however, that "indirect dowry" is not a translation of a Chinese term, nor does it reflect the way Chinese conceptualized marriage gifts and payments.

Although we have agreed to use these terms in the ways described here, we have not fooled ourselves into thinking that such labeling solves all of our problems of classification and analysis. For instance, several of us have difficulty employing the vocabulary of dowry and indirect dowry, with the implication that these two are similar in that in either case the property ends up with the woman. In the Chinese case, lumping these two together may be useful for short-term perspectives (a woman with a substantial dowry may have status and power other women do not, whether the dowry came entirely from her parents or indirectly from her parents-in-law) but is inadequate for looking at the larger transfer of property over time. In China the notion of individual property rights was weak, circumscribed by the claims of potential heirs. The heirs to a woman's dowry were her sons and thus the patriline of her husband. Indirect dowry that originated from her husband's patriline would therefore end there also. This pattern is in marked contrast to the situation where a woman's parents detach part of their property and permanently transfer it to the patriline of her husband, giving her trusteeship during her lifetime. As this discussion makes clear, however, this distinction is relevant only to property that can be passed to heirs. Clothes, bedding, and even furniture would probably be worn out by the time the woman dies. A distinction between dowries in land or ones in movable goods would still not solve this problem because in a commercialized society like late imperial China cash could be used to buy land, and land could be sold to meet current expenses, such as funerals. Moreover, whether a wife's dowry served to enlarge the estate of her sons would depend not merely on the initial assortment of goods but also on how it was used and managed over the years.

Imperial Marriages

Rather than introduce the chapters of this volume chronologically, I will highlight some of the relationships among them by looking at marriage at three social levels: the imperial family and clan, the educated elite, and ordinary people. For the premodern period, there are more studies of the marriages of imperial families and clans than of any other segment of society. There have been studies of the families from which empresses and other consorts were selected, the kinds of families chosen to provide husbands for princesses, the methods used to keep empresses or their kin from gaining too


9

much political power, and the needs of imperial families to exemplify ritually correct behavior in marriage practices and male-female differentiation (see de Crespigny 1975; Holmgren 1981, 1981-83, 1983, 1986; Wong 1979; Chung 1981; Soullière 1988). These studies place imperial marriage policies firmly within imperial politics; they deal both with the efforts of the throne to safeguard or enhance its political control and of other groups to use marriage to gain greater access to political power. From these studies we know that by marrying their daughter to an emperor or future emperor, a family could gain not merely prestige and wealth but also office. Years later its officials might have considerable influence in court affairs, especially if the daughter gave birth to the next ruler. Women were pivotal figures between the two families in imperial marriages and could sometimes make use of their position to gain exceptional power.

The theoretical literature on marriage discussed above offers new ways to approach imperial marriages. Is political power another resource that can be allocated through marriage, like wealth and prestige? Does the inevitable hypergamy and hypogamy of imperial marriages make them exceptional or only extreme? How did the public nature of imperial marriages affect the relations of the spouses or their families?

Three of the essays in this volume examine imperial marriages and the social, political, and gender inequalities they involved. In a path-breaking analysis, Jennifer Holmgren identifies the underlying structural logic of Han Chinese imperial marriages. Recurrent features can be explained, she argues, by the conjunction of the basic Chinese marriage system—monogamy, surname exogamy, women's continuing links to their natal families, and filial piety—on the one hand, with the unique requirements of succession to the throne by a single heir on the other. Because the emperors regularly forced collateral lines, even their brothers and adult younger sons, to leave the capital, the emperors' wives and mothers (empresses, empress dowagers, and grand empress dowagers) often played leading roles in decisions concerning succession and marriage, and their families could sometimes dominate the bureaucracy. Yet in many ways emperors' sisters had stronger positions than empresses, as they could come or go from the palace, were immune from punishment, could dominate their husbands, and could influence their brother the emperor even if he were a strong-minded adult. In tracing historical examples of these processes, Holmgren argues provocatively that changes in imperial marriage, such as the Ming practice of selecting imperial wives from nonelite families, were unrelated to changes in marriage practices in the larger society. Rather, she asserts that imperial marriage patterns are entirely explicable by reference to imperial politics and the underlying logic already described.

Holmgren contrasts these Han Chinese marriage patterns to those of several non-Han stares whose native marriage systems allowed polygyny,


10

the levirate, and marriage to distant agnates and generally fell more on the side of bridewealth than dowry societies. The imperial families of these states developed several different marriage systems, the T'o-pa of the Northern Wei denying any power to the mothers of emperors, the Ch'i-tan of the Liao marrying exclusively with one consort clan, and the Mongols of the Yuan marrying with the rulers of allied tribes, preventing their women from gaining control of the throne by allowing succession only to adult sons.

Holmgren's broad overview is complemented here by close studies of imperial marriages in two dynasties, one Han and one non-Han. John W. Chaffee examines the marriages of imperial clanswomen in the Sung dynasty, thus shifting the focus from control of the throne to the use of marriage as a means of connecting the civil elite to the large imperial clan with its thousands of members. He pays particular attention to the issue of hypogamy and the symbolic and political complexities of marriages in which the wife outranked her husband and his parents. His evidence shows clearly that even at a considerable distance from the throne, marriages involved a significant distribution of wealth and privileges. Imperial clanswomen had to be married into the elite not merely to help the throne forge ties to the political elite but also to avoid the dishonor of having its women marry too low. Given the size of the imperial clan, these marriages were decided not by the emperor but by a bureaucracy in which members of the official elite played leading roles.

In her study of the marriages of the Manchu rulers of the Ch'ing dynasty, Evelyn S. Rawski focuses on those closest to the throne, the sons and daughters of emperors and the emperor himself. The Ch'ing forbade intermarriage between the Manchu rulers and the civil elite of Han Chinese officials, thus using marriage to maintain the distinct identity of their special followers, the Chinese and Manchu bannermen. Whereas the Ch'ing adopted the traditional Han Chinese ritual code for wedding ceremonies, they did not adopt other, perhaps more fundamental, elements of Han marriage practices. In particular, Ch'ing empresses were not as powerful as their counterparts had been in Han Chinese dynasties because their sons were not the presumptive heirs. Rawski thus concurs with Holmgren that the differences in the marriage systems of different dynasties were closely related to differences in their succession practices.

Rawski makes the intriguing point that Manchu imperial marriages are difficult to classify as either monogamous or polygamous. As she sees it, a highly fluid set of social relations was made to appear sharply stratified by ritual and institutional distinctions not simply between the empress and consorts but also between each of the seven grades of consort. In reality, the mode of entry, social background, and privileges of these women, she argues, were not clearly distinguished, in contrast to Han commoner practice. Particularly significant was the emperor's right to promote his mother to empress


11

dowager after he succeeded to the throne, leading to two empress dowagers in the senior generation (his father's empress and his mother).

These three chapters contribute not only to our understanding of imperial governance in China but also to our knowledge of Chinese marriage mythology. Stories about the marriages of emperors and princesses—along with the marriages of the rulers of preimperial states discussed in Thatcher's chapter—provided much of the stock of images used to think about marriage and affinal relations in Chinese society at large. The dangers of matrilateral or affinal interference were underlined to all by stories of emperors who had been reduced to puppets by powerful "outside" relatives. Indeed, the treachery and scheming of women were easily evoked by stories of the machinations of women close to the throne, from empress dowagers to slave girls.

Elite Marriages

Besides studies of imperial marriages, the existing literature on marriage in Chinese history includes detailed research on marriage connections among social and political elites. Studies of marriage from the late Han through the T'ang period have shown that the highest-ranking families marry as much as possible within their own ranks and use such marriages as markers of status. The state sporadically attempted to regulate these practices either by ruling that marriages must be confined to status equals or by attempting to prohibit exclusive practices that undermined the state's ability to control honor and prestige (Twitchett 1973; D. Johnson 1977b; Ebrey 1978; Wong 1979; Mather 1980).

After mid-T'ang, the state paid little attention to the marriage choices of political elites. The elite of the Sung dynasty and later are generally viewed as less closed than those of earlier periods, and historians have tended to look at their marriages as creating networks rather than closed circles. Robert Hymes has studied the marriages linking seventy-three elite families in Fuchou, Kiangsi, in the Sung and Yuan (1986a; 1986b). He generally assumes that these marriages were motivated by political strategies. When officials' families had less need of ties to other official families, they used the occasion of their children's marriages to strengthen their links to local landowners and literati. Beverly Bossler has examined in similar detail the marriages of the national elite that resided in Kaifeng in the Northern Sung. Her findings raise doubts about the notion that marriages were politically motivated; she does not always find families following what has been thought to be the politically advantageous course or reaping the assumed benefits when they did (Bossler 1988). In a study of the Wu lineage of Hsiu-ning City, Hui-chou, during the Ming, Keith Hazelton found that lineage members had extensive


12

marriage networks; about two-thirds of Wu wives came from nine different surnames, and no single surname accounted for more than 15 percent of the total (Hazelton 1986:158-60). By contrast, Hilary Beattie showed that the two most prominent lineages of T'ung-ch'eng in Ch'ing times intermarried for five generations, Yao women providing a majority of the wives of Chang men in several lines for two or three generations in a row (1979:104-5). Jerry Dennerline found a comparable situation in nineteenth-century Wu-hsi, with about a third of the marriages of one line of Ch'iens to Hua families. He shows that such patterns went back to the early Ming in some lines, while other lines, for various strategic reasons, had spread their marriages much more broadly (Dennerline 1986:181-86). The diverse patterns uncovered by these case studies demonstrate above all the flexibility of the ways marriage connections could be used by members of the elite in the late imperial period. Benefits were to be gained by alliances to powerful lineages in one's home area. But creating affinal links to as many families as possible also offered advantages, as did ignoring politics in some marriages and emphasizing instead property exchanges.

Three chapters in this volume complement these studies of elite marriages. Each focuses on a period of major social change and thus aids, in a preliminary way, our understanding of how changes in Chinese society were connected to shifts in marriage structures. Melvin Thatcher examines elite intermarriage patterns for an earlier period than attempted before, the part of the mid-Chou called the Spring and Autumn period. Besides describing basic marriage rules and practices, he examines the bilateral marriage relations among the ruling houses of the separate states of this period. According to his evidence, already in the Spring and Autumn period ritual and ideology were used to distinguish women by rank into wives and concubines of various grades, a distinction reiterated in other chapters. Moreover, marriages were already marked by property transactions. Although the main assets of the period (fiefs, offices, and land grants) could not be conveyed through marriage, grooms' families made gifts of cloth to brides' families, and brides might bring with them clothes, jewels, maids, or even bronze vessels. Men in the ruling elite could have more than one primary wife (unlike in later periods), and divorce was relatively easy and common. In this and other ways Thatcher's portrayal of the marriage system of this aristocratic society suggests parallels with some of the non-Han societies Holmgren describes. In these less bureaucratized societies marriage and kinship played larger roles in the structuring of political relations than they typically did in imperial China.

Thatcher's chapter can be usefully contrasted with mine, in which I link political strategies and property transfers. I argue that in the T'ang, when the aristocratic families depended on the inherited prestige of their family names, marriages with particular families could confer enormous honor and


13

be worth the expenditure of large sums for betrothal gifts. In the Sung, when the prestige of old family status was much diminished and bureaucratic rank more highly valued, the elite often sent their daughters into marriage with large dowries, even of land. During this period many of the features of the dowry complex Goody has described as common in Eurasia were evident in China. Not only were there monogamy and parental control of marriages (well established at least by the Han), but also the landowning class transmitted significant amounts of property through daughters, and women's claims to dowry received some legal recognition. In exploring reasons for this trend toward larger transfers through dowry, I suggest that economic changes, such as freer transfer of land and commercialization, were preconditions. The political value of connections then served to push these trends further. Dowries made better bait than betrothal gifts because property was permanently transferred to the other line and affinal ties were stronger when both sides had lingering claims to property.

Susan Mann's chapter deals with another dimension of elite marriages: the connections writers saw between marriage and gender differentiation. Much of the existing research on marriage in Chinese history concerns the ideology of the ideal wife and the cult of widow chastity (see Swann 1932; O'Hara 1971; Ropp 1976; Holmgren 1981, 1985; Sung 1981; Waltner 1981; Elvin 1984; Mann 1985, 1987). It is by now well established that ideals of womanhood changed over time for reasons that varied from ethnic antagonisms to concerns for men's political loyalties and anxieties about status. Moreover, it can be shown that even constant ideals had different effects on behavior in different periods, depending on the incentives provided by property law, kinship groups, charitable ventures, and government honors. These studies show that we need to keep in mind how ideology and state power worked with the transfer of property in creating gender inequalities in China. In her chapter here, Mann brings the rhetoric on women's spheres into the discussion of elite marriage practices. She argues that the remarkable social mobility of the mid-Ch'ing period led to anxiety about the blurring of boundaries between people of different status, including the boundaries between wives and lower-status women. Literati writers of this period reexamined classical writings on marriage rituals and the proper roles of husbands and wives, emphasizing not wives' subordination but the ways they complemented their husbands by taking charge in their own spheres. Valorizing the role of wife, the literati placed much of the task of protecting family and class honor on wives and daughters.

Taken together, the three chapters on elite marriage show us three sides of marriage and also three points in time. The politics of alliance were never absent from elite marriages, but they were probably also never so well developed as they were among the ruling families of the Chou, where marriage had important links to succession by a single heir and where rulers needed


14

alliances transcending their borders. Property, again, could never have been a trivial consideration in elite marriages, but the amounts involved seem to have become a particular concern in the T'ang-Sung period, and changes in the nature and direction of transfers were complexly associated with commercialization and increased competition for elite status. Nor was concern with the meaning of marriage new to the Ch'ing. Since the time when the ritual classics were written, writers had tried to deny or transcend the political and financial aspects of marriage and to reconcile the fact that marriages entailed not just unions of families but unions of men and women. Yet these efforts gained special urgency in the eighteenth century with the greater commercialization of society and the instability of social boundaries.

Property and the Marriages of Ordinary People

English-language studies of gender differentiation in premodern China have tended to concentrate on ideology, yet there is also a large literature, especially in Chinese and Japanese, on the history of marriage as a legal institution. Laws on family property, divorce, exogamy, incest, bigamy, adultery, and rape shaped the marriage practices of men and women in all social classes. Studies of marriage-related law are the basis for our characterization of traditional China as a society that practiced monogamy, concubinage, divorce, and adoption and followed a property regime that favored transmission through males (see Ch'ü 1965; McCreery 1976; Dull 1978; Tai 1978; Shiga 1978; Meijer 1981; Ng 1987; Ocko 1989). Since Engels's time, scholars have argued that the subordination of women was a result of their inferior property rights. Accordingly, scholars studying the legal and economic position of women in modern China have often drawn on these studies of traditional law, either as evidence of what China was like before modern reforms or as keys to understanding the traditional social forms that persisted into modern times.

Three chapters in this volume build on these prior studies of legal institutions to reconsider how women related to property. Focusing on the Hong Kong region in the early twentieth century, Rubie S. Watson analyzes the social and legal distinctions among wives, concubines, and maids. She argues that a crucial distinction between wives and concubines was the property transaction that marked their marriages, then goes on to examine the consequences that flow from these differences. In other words, she does not stop at the distribution of property, but looks at the consequences for the distribution of power, respect, and security within the domestic sphere. She stresses the importance of dowry in giving women the dignity of wives and the autonomy of property holders. Wives even had advantages over their husbands in one regard: they could have private property separate from the larger family property. Concubines not only lacked private funds but also usually lacked contact with their natal families and thus could not provide effective matri-


15

lateral relatives for their children. Maids were not permanent members of the household, but merely indentured servants until marriage or concubinage. Their lives were often harsh while in service, and when they left it was often to become a concubine in another household.

Although dowry seems indubitably to have enhanced a woman's prestige and autonomy, and the more dowry the better, the relation between women's status and money was not simply linear. Gail Hershatter's chapter on prostitution in early twentieth-century Shanghai shows that money, status, and autonomy were much more complexly related. The highest prices were paid for beautiful preadolescent girls who could be trained to serve the male elite. They lived in much greater comfort than lower-class prostitutes but were also watched more closely by their owners and faced much greater obstacles to getting out of prostitution because their owners would demand much higher redemption fees. Prostitution illustrates the extremes to which the commodification of women could go. Prostitutes had little control over their lives. Others sold or pawned them into prostitution; madames decided which clients they would accept; only with outside help did they have any chance to leave "the life." The existence of the market for prostitutes made it clear to all that there was a price for women. To a peasant family, a daughter was worth so much as a bride, so much as a maid, so much as a prostitute. Prostitution in China was treated as a legal contractual arrangement in which one owner of a woman sold or pawned her to another.

Jonathan K. Ocko explores in more depth the role of the state in defining and enforcing the links between property and women in his chapter in this volume. In the Ch'ing code, women's relation to property, unlike men's, was nearly always mediated by marriage. Whatever property a woman got from her natal family came as a marriage portion; whatever claims she had to the use of her husband's estate after his death depended on her staying there, not leaving her husband's family to marry someone else. In the twentieth century, new laws fundamentally altered the legal basis of gender differentiation, and Ocko examines the revisions of the law code aimed at improving women's property rights, especially the 1950 and 1980 marriage laws and the 1985 inheritance law. He shows that despite the persistence of long-held cultural notions now labeled "feudal," some real change is discernible, above all in the rights of widows to inherit from their husbands. In the Ch'ing widows were trustees for the heirs, but only if they did not remarry. In current law, admittedly not always enforced, widows own in their own right half of the community property of the marriage and inherit half of their husband's share; moreover, they are free to take this property into another marriage. Changes in behavior, Ocko shows, have lagged far behind changes in the law. Disjunctures between economic organization and legal strictures are probably partly to blame, as is the political instability of judicial institutions. In recent decades punishment of transgressions appears to have been sporadic.

The market aspects of marriage are viewed differently in William Lavely's


16

chapter. Lavely examines how the marriage market served to alter women's economic circumstances (or, to put it another way, how economically desirable homes were distributed to young women through the mechanisms of a marriage market). He sees mate selection as largely explicable in market terms but does not see dowry and betrothal gifts as the most significant factors in decisions. Drawing on statistical evidence of the movements of women in a region of Szechwan in the 1970s, he infers that wife-givers were maximizing their daughters' comfort, not their own, and wife-takers were looking for better-educated brides from nearby areas, not simply ones that could be had for the least expense or who would bring the most goods (though they may have been expected to earn more income). As he stresses, comparing the process of mate selection to a market does not mean that people are bought and sold; it means that those making the decisions weigh all of the pros and cons of each possibility and try to maximize their advantage. His assumption that parents and their daughters can be seen as having a single interest in these transactions is, however, in direct conflict with Rubie Watson's argument that individual members of a household did not share the same interests or the same agenda.

These four chapters on marriage in the twentieth century bring us into intellectual engagement with the debates on the degree to which state power has been used to improve women's status in the twentieth century (see Croll 1981; Stacey 1983; K. Johnson 1983; Wolf 1985). They also provide insight into marriage in traditional times. They draw on the abundant documentation of the twentieth century, but the phenomena they analyze are not new to this period. Certainly the buying and selling of concubines and prostitutes were common features of Chinese society for many centuries (Ebrey 1986). Likewise, the more general commodification of women is not a new phenomenon, though scholars do not yet agree how far back to date its more extreme forms (see Ropp 1987; Gates 1989). Nor was the relationship between the law and behavior likely to have been any less complex in earlier times. Indeed, one would expect that the text of the law was if anything more clearly understood in contemporary times than in earlier ones. Even the geographic dimension of marriage inequality must have existed in earlier times, though without migration registers we may not be able to analyze it with any precision. Thus, these chapters can be read on two levels, as analyses of dimensions of marriage and inequality and as studies of twentieth-century conditions.

The Historical Development of Marriage in China

The research presented in this volume provides a preliminary basis for thinking about the historical development of marriage in China and how it fits into some of the larger comparative frameworks discussed at the beginning of this


17

essay. At the conference we frequently marveled at the continuities in Chinese marriage practices. Wedding rituals, exogamy rules, and concubinage showed many similarities from the aristocrats of the classical Chou period well into modern times. From classical times on, marriages involved transfers of property through betrothal gifts and often also dowry. Even ideological writings about marriage continually asserted that marriage served both the family and society by allowing the perpetuation of the patrilineal descent line, creating alliances between families of different surnames, and differentiating the proper spheres of men and women. At the imperial level, empresses and their relatives continued to be seen as potential threats to concentration of power in the person of the emperor and his legitimate male heirs. In the twentieth century, despite radical social, political, and economic reorganization, conceptions of women as property have proved remarkably persistent.

Nevertheless, our research generally supports the proposition that increasing social and economic differentiation and state development in China were accompanied by tendencies toward the dowry complex. Chinese history is commonly divided into four periods—the ancient, early imperial, late imperial, and modern—based on changes in the state, elite, economy, and culture. The most visible changes in marriage institutions can also be roughly correlated with these broader historical transitions. In ancient times, as Thatcher shows, polygyny was allowed among the ruling elite, divorce was easy, and the key assets passed along the male line were not transmitted in marriages. Although Thatcher stresses the congruences he finds with Goody's model—such as marriages among social equals and strong ties between women and their natal families—I am more struck by what is missing. Later, in the Han, the centralized bureaucratic government was consolidated, hereditary aristocracy abolished, buying and selling of land made legally easy, and the small family established as the key kinship unit. In the new social and economic order, marriage became legally monogamous, divorce legally easy for men but socially difficult, succession less of an issue as there were fewer fiefs or offices to succeed to, and property, when inherited, was divided equally among all sons. Legal monogamy, in particular, was an important step toward the Eurasian dowry complex model. In late imperial times (Sung-Ch'ing), with a more commercialized economy and more competition for social status and political office, dowry itself was much more in evidence. Ideology, if anything, gave greater stress to the permanence of marriage, though not in the same way as in Europe (i.e., widow remarriage, not divorce, was the symbolically significant issue).

At least as important, historically, as these movements toward the dowry complex is the evidence that this complex did not develop fully. In no period was China a dowry society comparable, for instance, to India (cf. Tambiah 1973). In late imperial times, even prosperous families might pass very little


18

property through their daughters. Nowhere did custom or law force families with sons to give daughters shares of property at all comparable to the sons'. Although the state took considerable interest in the orderly and equitable division of family property among sons, it did not mandate provision of dowries. After marriage, wives' dowries were given some protection from the members of the larger family into which the woman had married, but less from their husbands. As discussed in my chapter, orphaned daughters' claims to dowries were legally strengthened in Sung times, and widows' claims to retain their dowries even if they remarried were widely recognized, but the Ming witnessed a reversal of these gains, not undone until modern times. Moreover, one might note that at the imperial level some trends went against the direction of the dowry complex: as Holmgren notes, in Ming times the emperor's spouses came from unimportant families who could not maintain close ties to the throne.

By way of conclusion, I would like to explore in a tentative and speculative way some of the reasons why the dowry complex did not develop more fully in China. As best I can reconstruct from the limited research done so far, China's economy in some important respects favored the dowry complex, yet Confucian ideology and state-established legal institutions obstructed its full development.

The relationship of the state to the dowry complex was multifaceted; in many ways it can be seen as fostering it. State power underlay the system of private ownership of land and its relatively easy alienability and as a consequence the kind of class system based on highly unequal ownership of productive resources. It is under this sort of political economy that the features associated with the dowry complex have most frequently developed. Moreover, the state also facilitated advances in commercialization through maintenance of transportation networks, currency, and so on; commercialization, as I argue in chapter 3, facilitated using wealth to acquire useful social ties through the mechanism of dowered marriages. In the later imperial period the civil service recruitment system made it progressively more difficult for men to pass on their political rank to their sons, assuring that wealth, not office, would be the fundamental underpinning of long-term family status.

At the same time, the Confucian-educated elite and the legal institutions of the state erected obstacles to the transmission of property through women. Many Confucian scholars denied that women had rights or claims to property, their objections apparently based on fears of women gaining undue importance. To them, deviation from strict adherence to transmission of property along patrilineal lines could undermine the whole family system and thus implicitly erode the authority of senior males (e.g., Ebrey 1984a:231). On the issue of affines and matrilateral relatives, Confucian family ideology was relatively silent. Much was said about domestic family relations, including the relationships of husbands and wives, the social relationships of agnat-


19

ic kinsmen, and the ceremonies to be performed for weddings and funerals, but little about how to treat wives' brothers or cousins through mothers. No standards were articulated for the choice of families for marriage partners except in the vaguest ways (spouses, for instance, should not be chosen on the basis of transient wealth or rank), nor was much said about how to interact with them after the wedding. The only widely discussed examples were the cautionary ones of the imperial family. Confucian ideology was reinforced by and reflected in the state's legal codes. The law required monogamy but otherwise contained nothing that would explicitly foster the dowry complex—not requiring daughters to be given dowries, or granting wives clear control over dowries in their possession, or granting wives' natal kin any say in disposition of her dowry after her death.

Were anyone's interests served by inhibiting the dowry complex? Consciously, writers opposed to women's control of property saw it as threatening to male authority, to hierarchy in general, and to the preservation of patrimonies. There may well be some truth to these perceptions, though patriliny and patriarchy were able to coexist with dowry and female inheritance in other parts of the world.[2] But limiting the transmission of property through women also discouraged full development of the organizational potential inherent in affinal ties. Thus, educated men who condemned women's control of property. may have been acting in their interests as male family heads but not in their interests as members of a social and political elite that sought greater independence from the government. Connections, including affinal connections, provided ways to get around many obstacles to advancement and influence; as seen throughout this volume such ties were regularly used by elite men at the local, regional, and national level. The manipulation of marriage choices also served the interests of the elite because belonging to a relatively restricted circle of intermarrying families could serve as proof of elite status.

Following this line of thinking, it was the state, as an entity with interests in the efficiency, accountability, and predictability of the actions of its employees, that benefited from discouraging any further strengthening of matrilateral and affinal ties among the elite. If through its legal institutions the state had given more protection to dowries—assuring the return of the dowry if the wife died early without heirs or was divorced for a cause like barrenness—China might have evolved into a society with stronger bilateral tendencies and greater proclivities to organize along affinal lines. But emperors and their advisers saw nothing to gain from such a situation. Strong dynasties seem never to have encouraged the highest-ranking families to marry with each other either by providing incentives or by asserting the moral desirability of such matches. Emperors did not chide leading ministers for being too casual in the selection of their children's mates, or remind them that they had their honor to uphold, as European kings might their nobles.


20

This is probably because within the bureaucracy marriage connections were less visible and therefore more threatening to imperial control and bureaucratic rationality than patrilineal kinship ties. The government could easily suspect that two people from the same place with the same family name might be patrilineal relatives and take their likely bias into account. If men also sided with their sisters' husbands, wives' brothers, father's sister's sons, mother's sisters' and brothers' sons, and so on, too many surnames would be involved for anyone to keep track who did not know them closely. How much easier it is for the state if these affinal ties are weak.

The failure of the Chinese educated class and imperial state to encourage dowries, women's property rights, strong ties among affines, or intermarriage among elites did not prevent the "sprouts" of these developments, but it probably prevented these trends from going as far as they might have otherwise. In contrast to societies where the dowry complex was fostered by the ideologies of dominant institutions, China should be seen as a place where it was kept within limits by both ideology and state actions.

Glossary

chi-shihinline image

ch'iinline image

chia-chuanginline image

ch'iehinline image

chuang-lieninline image

fu-jeninline image

hou-shihinline image

li-chininline image

na-ts'aiinline image

p'in-chininline image

p'in-liinline image

p'in-ts'aiinline image

shihinline image

shih-jeninline image

ts'e-shihinline image

tzu-chuanginline image

tzu-sunginline image

yinginline image

References

Ahern, Emily M. 1974. "Affines and the Rituals of Kinship." In Religion and Ritual in' Chinese Society , ed. Arthur P. Wolf. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Baker, Hugh H. D. 1979. Chinese Family and Kinship . London: Macmillan.


21

Beattie, Hilary J. 1979. Land and Lineage in China: A Study of T'ung-ch'eng County, Anhwei, in the Ming and Ch'ing Dynasties . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Bossler, Beverly. 1988. "Northern Sung Elite Families in K'ai-feng." Manuscript.

Bourdieu, Pierre. 1976. "Marriage Strategies as Strategies of Social Reproduction." In Family and Society: Selections from the Annales, Economies, Societies, Civilisations , ed. Robert Forster and Orest Ranum. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Chaffee, John W. 1985. The Thorny Gates of Learning: A Social History of Examinations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Chang, K. C. 1983. Art, Myth, and Ritual: The Path to Political Authority in Ancient China . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Chen, Chung-min. 1985. "Dowry and Inheritance." In The Chinese Family and Its Ritual Behavior , ed. Hsieh Jih-chang and Chuang Ying-chang. Taipei: Academia Sinica, Institute of Ethnology.

Ch'ü, T'ung-tsu. 1965. Law and Society in Traditional China . Paris: Mouton.

Chung, Priscilla Ching. 1981. Palace Women in the Northern Sung, 960-1126 . Monographies du T'oung Pao, no. 12. Leiden: E. J. Brill.

Cohen, Myron L. 1976. House United, House Divided: The Chinese Family in Taiwan . New York: Columbia University Press.

———. 1988. "Marriage Finance in Contemporary Hopei." Talk given at the Conference on Marriage and Inequality in Chinese Society.

Collier, Jane Fishburne, and Sylvia Junko Yanagisako. 1987. "Introduction." In Gender and Kinship: Essays Toward a Unified Analysis , ed. Jane Fishburne Collier and Sylvia Junko Yanagisako. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Comaroff, J. L. 1980. "Introduction." In The Meaning of Marriage Payments , ed. J. L. Comaroff. New York: Academic Press.

Croll, Elisabeth. 1981. The Politics of Marriage in Contemporary China . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

de Crespigny, Rafe. 1975. "The Harem of Emperor Huan: A Study of Court Politics in Later Han." Papers on Far Eastern History 12:1-42.

Dennerline, Jerry. 1986. "Marriage, Adoption, and Charity in the Development of Lineages in Wu-hsi from Sung to Ch'ing." In Kinship Organization in Late Imperial China, 1000-1940 , ed. Patricia Buckley Ebrey and James L. Watson. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Duby, Georges. 1978. Medieval Marriage: Two Models from Twelfth-Century France . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Dull, Jack. 1978. "Marriage and Divorce in Han China: A Glimpse at 'Pre-Confucian' Society." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Dumont, Louis. 1957. Hierarchy and Marriage Alliance in South Indian Kinship . London: Royal Anthropological Institute.

Ebrey, Patricia Buckley. 1978. The Aristocratic Families of Early Imperial China: A Case Study of the Po-ing Ts'ui Family . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1981. "Women in the Kinship System of the Southern Song Upper Class." Historical Reflections 8:113-28.

———. 1984a. "Conceptions of the Family in the Sung Dynasty." Journal of Asian Studies 43:219-45.

———. 1984b. Family and Property in Sung China: Yüan Ts'ai's Precepts for Social Life . Princeton: Princeton University Press.


22

———. 1986. "Concubines in Sung China." Journal of Family History 11:1-24.

Elvin, Mark. 1984. "Female Virtue and the State in China." Past and Present 104:111-152.

Fei, Hsiao-t'ung. 1939. Peasant Life in China . New York: Dutton.

Freedman, Maurice. 1957. Chinese Family and Marriage in Singapore . London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.

———. 1958. Lineage Organization in Southeastern China . London: Athlone Press.

———. 1979. The Study of Chinese Society , ed. G. William Skinner. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Gallin, Bernard. 1960. "Matrilateral and Affinal Relationships of a Taiwanese Village." American Anthropologist 62:632-42.

Gallin, Bernard, and Rita S. Gallin. 1985. "Matrilateral and Affinal Relationships in Changing Chinese Society." In The Chinese Family and Its Ritual Behavior , ed. Hsieh Jih-chang and Chuang Ying-chang. Taipei: Academia Sinica, Institute of Ethnology.

Gamble, Sidney D. 1954. Ting Hsien: A North China Rural Community . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Gates, Hill. 1989. "The Commoditization of Chinese Women." Signs 14:799-832.

Goody, Jack. 1973. "Bridewealth and Dowry in Africa and Eurasia." In Bridewealth and Dowry , by Jack Goody and S. J. Tambiah. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1976a. "Inheritance, Property and Women: Some Comparative Perspectives." In Family and Inheritance: Rural Society in Western Europe 1200-1800 , ed. Jack Goody, Joan Thirsk, and E. P. Thompson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1976b. Production and Reproduction: A Comparative Study of the Domestic Domain . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Harrell, Stevan, and Sara A. Dickey. 1985. "Dowry Systems in Complex Societies." Ethnology 24.2:105-20.

Hazelton, Keith. 1986. "Patrilines and the Development of Localized Lineages: The Wu of Hsiu-ning City, Hui-chou, to 1528." In Kinship Organization in Late Imperial China, 1000-1940 , ed. Patricia Buckley Ebrey and James L. Watson. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Holmgren, Jennifer. 1981. "Widow Chastity in the Northern Dynasties: The Lieh-nü Biographies in the Wei-shu." Papers on Far Eastern History 23:165-86.

———. 1981-83. "Women and Political Power in the Traditional T'o-pa Elite: A Preliminary Study of the Biographies of Empresses in the Wei-shu." Monumenta Serica 35:33-74.

———. 1983. "The Harem in Northern Wei Politics—398-498 A.D. " Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 26:71-90.

———. 1985. "The Economic Foundations of Virtue: Widow-Remarriage in Early and Modern China." Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 13:1-27.

——— 1986. "Marriage, Kinship and Succession under the Ch'i-tan Rulers of the Liao Dynasty (907-1125)." T'oung Pao 72:44-91.

Hsu, Francis L. K. 1948; rev. ed., 1971. Under the Ancestors' Shadow: Kinship, Personality, and Social Mobility in China . Stanford: Stanford University Press.


23

Hymes, Robert P. 1986a. "Marriage, Descent Groups, and the Localist Strategy in Sung and Yuan Fu-chou." In Kinship Organization in Late Imperial China, 1000-1940 , ed. Patricia Buckley Ebrey and James L. Watson. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

———. 1986b. Statesmen and Gentlemen: The Elite of Fu-chou, Chiang-hsi, in Northern and Southern Sung . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Inden, Ronald. 1976. Marriage and Rank in Bengali Culture . Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Johnson, David G. 1977a. "The Last Years of a Great Clan: The Li Family of Chao chün in Late T'ang and Early Sung." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 37:5-102.

———. 1977b. The Medieval Chinese Oligarchy . Boulder: Westview Press.

Johnson, Kay Ann. 1983. Women, the Family and Peasant Revolution in China . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Kulp, Daniel Harrison. 1925. Country Life in South China: The Sociology of Familism . New York: Teachers College Bureau of Publications.

Lang, Olga. 1946. Chinese Family and Society . New Haven: Yale University Press.

Leach, Edmund. 1954. The Political Systems of Highland Burma . London: Athlone Press.

McCreery, John L. 1976. "Women's Property Rights and Dowry in China and South Asia." Ethnology 15:163-74.

Mann, Susan. 1985. "Historical Change in Female Biography from Song to Qing Times: The Case of Early Qing Jiangnan (Jiangsu and Anhui Provinces)." Transactions of the International Confrence of Orientalists in Japan 30:65-77.

———. 1987. "Women in the Kinship, Class, and Community Structures of Qing Dynasty China." Journal of Asian Studies 46:37-56.

Mather, Richard B. 1980. "Intermarriage as a Gauge of Family Status in the Southern Dynasties." Paper presented at the Conference on the Nature of State and Society in Medieval China.

Mauss, Marcel. 1925; reprint, 1966. The Gift: Forms and Functions of Exchange in Archaic Societies . New York: Norton.

Meijer, M. J. 1981. "The Price of a P'ai-lou." T'oung Pao 67:288-304.

Ng, Vivienne W. 1987. "Ideology and Sexuality: Rape Laws in Qing China." Journal of Asian Studies 46:57-70.

Ocko, Jonathan. 1990. "Family Disharmony as Seen in Ch'ing Legal Cases." In Orthodoxy in Late Imperial China , ed. Kwang-ching Liu. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

O'Hara, Albert Richard. 1971. The Position of Women in Early China . Taipei: Mei Ya.

Ortner, Sherry. 1981. "Gender and Sexuality in Hierarchical Societies: The Case of Polynesia and Some Comparative Implications." In Sexual Meanings: The Cultural Construction of Gender and Sexuality , ed. Sherry Ortner and Harriet Whitehead. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Parry, Jonathan. 1979. Caste and Kinship in Kangra . London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

Parish, William L., and Martin King Whyte. 1978. Village and Family in Contemporary China . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Pasternak, Burton. 1972. Kinship and Community in Two Chinese Villages . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Ropp, Paul S. 1976. "The Seeds of Change: Reflections on the Condition of Women in Early and Mid Ch'ing." Signs 2:5-23.

———. 1987. "The Status of Women in Mid-Qing China: Evidence from Letters,


24

Law, and Literature." Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Historical Association.

Shiga Shuzo. 1978. "Family Property and the Law of Inheritance in Traditional China." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Soullière, Ellen F. 1988. "The Imperial Marriages of the Ming Dynasty." Papers on Far Eastern History 37:15-42.

Stacey, Judith. 1983. Patriarchy and Socialist Revolution in China . Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Sung, Marina H. 1981. "The Chinese Lieh-nü Tradition." In Women in China , ed. Richard W. Guisso and Stanley Johannesen. Youngstown, N.Y.: Philo Press.

Swann, Nancy Lee. 1932. Pan Chao: Foremost Woman Scholar of China . New York: Century.

Tai, Yen-hui. 1978. "Divorce in Traditional Chinese Law." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Tambiah, S.J. 1973. "Dowry and Bridewealth, and the Property Rights of Women in South Asia." In Bridewealth and Dowry , by Jack Goody and S. J. Tambiah. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Twitchett, Denis. 1973. "The Composition of the T'ang Ruling Class: New Evidence from Tunhuang." In Perspectives on the T'ang , ed. Arthur F. Wright and Denis Twitchett. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Waltner, Ann. 1981. "Widows and Remarriage in Ming and Early Qing China." In Women in China , ed. Richard W. Guisso and Stanley Johannesen. Youngstown, N.Y.: Philo Press.

Watson, Rubie S. 1981. "Class Differences and Affinal Relations in South China." Man 16:593-615.

———. 1984. "Women's Property in Republican China: Rights and Practice." Republican China 10.1a:1-12.

———. 1985. Inequality among Brothers: Class and Kinship in South China . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Wolf, Arthur P., and Chieh-shan Huang. 1980. Marriage and Adoption in China, 1845-1945 . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Wolf, Margery, 1972. Women and the Family in Rural Taiwan . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

———. 1985. Revolution Postponed: Women in Contemporary China . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Wong, Sun-ming. 1979. "Confucian Ideal and Reality: Transformation of the Institution of Marriage in T'ang China (A.D. 618-907)." Ph.D. diss., University of Washington.

Yang, Martin C. 1945. A Chinese Village: Taitou, Shantung Province . New York: Columbia University Press.


25

One
Marriages of the Ruling Elite in the Spring and Autumn Period

Melvin P. Thatcher

This chapter provides an overview and preliminary analysis of the marriage practices of the ruling elite in the aristocratic society of the Spring and Autumn period (770-453 B.C. ).[1] Departing from previous Western-language investigations that frequently refer to classical ritual texts, such as the I-li and Li-chi (Granet 1920, 1930:152-60; Feng 1937:43-54), or draw on a narrow slice of historical data (Chang 1976:89-92, 1983:29-30), this is a study of references to marriage in the Ch'un-ch'iu and Tso-chuan , the most important primary sources for the Spring and Autumn period. It takes into account all 150 recorded marriages, but focuses on the 126 marriages that involve members of the ruling households,[2] namely, rulers, their sons, daughters, and grandsons. Analyzing these marriages has several purposes, the first of which is descriptive or classificatory. In this regard attention is given to the hierarchy of women in the ruler's household and to wedding rituals, marriage rules, and patterns of intermarriage. The second purpose of analyzing these marriages is to determine how aristocratic marriages were connected to the social and political systems of this period. The relation between marriage and inequality is very much at issue here; the evidence suggests that marriages were used above all to create and strengthen ties between social and political equals. The third purpose for analyzing these marriages is to provide a baseline for discussing continuities and discontinuities over the course of Chinese history.

The Chou dynasty (c. 1122-256 B.C. ) is divided into the Western Chou (c. 1122-771) and Eastern Chou (770-256) eras. The former began with the successful conquest of the Shang dynasty by the Chou people from their western base. Having defeated the Shang, the kings of Chou established pockets of power in conquered territory by installing close kin and trusted lieutenants as their representatives and by recognizing the de facto power of


26

local chieftains who were willing to acknowledge Chou suzerainty. This policy allowed them to extend the sphere of their territorial control, although it ultimately led to their decline and fall as the outposts became embryonic states and the descendants of their founders established themselves as ruling lineages. With self-interest eventually prevailing over the demands of clan and affinal ties and political loyalty to the ruling house of Chou, the stage was set for epochal change as two of the Chou statelets joined with barbarian forces to depose King Yu (r. 781-71) in 771. In the aftermath of this event, a new Chou capital was established eastward in the Central Plain where the royal house could be given better protection from its internal and external enemies. The Eastern Chou era was inaugurated (Creel 1970; Hsu 1984).

The Eastern Chou was a time of great social and political changes that ultimately produced a unified Chinese empire. The first part of this era, the Spring and Autumn period, saw the emergence of a multistate system that covered most of the drainage areas of the Yellow, Yangtze, and Huai rivers and their major tributaries (Walker 1953; Liu Po-ch'i 1962). By the end of the first century of this period, the kings of Chou, no longer able to exercise effective military might, had lost political influence and real control over the various states. The institution of hegemon (pa ) filled the power vacuum, and from 679, interstate relations were conducted through summitry and covenant making, with the most powerful state ruler holding sway as hegemon. In theory the functions of the hegemon were to respect the king of Chou, to repel barbarian invasions, and to protect the weaker states. An elaborate interstate protocol developed whereby the states, which are estimated to have initially numbered 124 or more (CCTSP 4:1a [1036, "Preface"]; Lü 1962:151-65), were ranked as first-rate (ta-kuo ), second-rate (tz'u-kuo ), and third-rate (hsia-kuo ) (TCCS 26:4a [437, Ch'eng 3]). As we shall see below, this protocol was reinforced through marriage rituals. Competition among the more powerful states for the hegemonship resulted in the elimination of numerous weaker states, despite the precautions taken to ensure their survival. By the beginning of the Warring States period (453-222), only seven major states and fourteen minor ones remained viable (K. Yang 1980: 261-65). The rivalry among states was an important factor in marriages between ruling houses.

Early in the Spring and Autumn period the elite was defined by membership in a state's ruling house or appointment to a ranked office. The ruler presided over an administration staffed by officials of ch'ing, tai-fu , and shih , or equivalent ranks. Whereas minor offices were usually passed on, like occupations, from father to son, ranked offices, particularly those of ch'ing and tai-fu rank, were often filled through appointment by the ruler. In states that followed the Chou practice of awarding land grants to meritorious officials and military officers, politically effective lineages arose and competition was keen among them for the hereditary right to ch'ing (ministerial) status (TCCS 36:


27

17a-18a [625, Hsiang 25]). Control over the appointment process became the object of struggles between ruling houses and local lineages. When lineages were able to win control and establish the hereditary right to ranked offices, inter- and intralineage competition ensued for possession of that right. The way was thus prepared for major social and political changes (Thatcher 1977-78, 1985). These contests for power and status entered into marriage choices and created unstable conditions that were conducive to social mobility for individuals and groups alike.

Largely because of the dynamics of domestic politics, social mobility prevailed at the upper reaches of society during the Spring and Autumn period. The king of Chou sat at the apex of society, followed in descending order by members of ruling households (namely, the rulers of states and their brothers, sons, and grandsons), officials of ch'ing, tai-fu , and shih rank, and the bulk of the population, mainly commoners. In his discussion of social stratification and mobility, Hsu Cho-yun argues that in the earliest decades of the Spring and Autumn period the brothers and sons of rulers declined in importance as officials of the ch'ing and tai-fu ranks came to dominate the political scene, and that in the waning years of the period shih began to appear in significant roles, presaging their dominance in the subsequent Warring States period (Hsu 1965:24-37). There was, in fact, mobility both within states and across state boundaries. Ruling lineages lost their status when their states were extinguished by more powerful neighbors, but some lineage members might be appointed to relatively low-level positions in the new regime. Most were reduced, however, to commoner or lower status. As newly powerful lineages within particular states were able to usurp the rights of older, more established lineages to ch'ing status, it was possible for whole groups to climb the social ladder, while those whom they displaced became commoners. This particular mobility becomes evident during the late seventh century B.C. and is seen most clearly in the state of Chin (Thatcher 1977-78:153-59).

Individual social mobility was also possible and occurred under a variety of circumstances. In states that were not totally dominated by powerful lineages, officials rose or fell according to their performance. The number of political exiles seeking asylum made it necessary to formulate rules to accommodate them in their host states. Some refugees were able to significantly improve their political fortunes and, consequently, their social status. The growing importance of shih toward the end of the period, as noted by Hsu Cho-yun, stemmed from the need for specialized functionaries at higher levels and a resulting deemphasis on lineage membership and position. At the bottom of the social ladder, slaves were manumitted (TCCS 35:12a [603, Hsiang 23]). Social mobility influenced individuals' marriage choices.

The economy of the Spring and Autumn period was based on intensive agriculture. In theory all land belonged to the king of Chou, but in practice it


28

was held by the rulers of states and aristocratic lineages. During much of the period, land could not be alienated or inherited by individuals. With the advent in the sixth century B.C. of iron implements, the ox-drawn plow, and taxation on land in various states, the seeds of land reform were sown and private ownership of land became possible. Nevertheless, lineage-held land remained the dominant form of landholding through the end of the period. In addition to agriculture, the local economies in the various states also included cottage industries that produced such products as iron, bronze, salt, `, and textiles. At the same time, commercial activity was growing with the establishment of marketplaces and appearance of merchants engaged in interstate transactions. Trade was conducted through barter, but toward the end of the period local currencies began to appear (Ch'i 1981:96-99; Liu et al. 1979:99-106; Tang 1982:6-64).

The Spring and Autumn kinship system was composed of patrilineal kin groups that can be classified as clans, lineages, and families.[3] Although patrilineages were distinguished by lineage names (shih ), those that shared a clan name (hsing ) regarded themselves as agnatic kinsmen (KY 10:7b [258, "Chin yü" 4]). A rule of clan exogamy was recognized, but it was frequently violated, as will be shown below. The patrilineage was the critical kin group in this aristocratic society. Patrilineages were segmentary, socially stratified organizations (Chang 1976:74-75). The generational depth of powerful Spring and Autumn lineages ranged from three to twenty generations (CCTSP 12a: 1a-43a and 12b: 1a-31b [1281-1318]).[4] The patrilineage was a corporate kin group, typically based on land held in common and on shared ancestral rites. Land was transmitted from generation to generation by males within the lineage. Movable property, however, could be owned and controlled by families, although there are no examples of its inheritance during this period. The rules of inheritance are therefore not clear. Succession to the headship of lineages and their segments was usually from father to son, but not necessarily to the eldest son, for all of a man's sons were eligible to become his successor. The patrilineage was the effective exogamous unit, and marriage choices were based on lineage or family considerations. Postmarital residence was usually patrilocal.[5]

Women held an inferior status in Eastern Chou society, evident in a postmarital naming system that suppressed the bride's given name, in the determination of a wife's rank and status by those of her husband, and in funerary practices whereby husbands, fathers, and sons were shown more respect than wives, mothers, and married daughters (Liu Te-han 1976:5-11). Chia Shih-heng argues that wives did not have the right to own private property, citing this as one cause for forced divorces in the Warring States period (1980:27). Although these generalizations pertain to the Eastern Chou as a whole, most are documentable in Spring and Autumn sources, particularly the points concerning discrimination in referential terms or


29

naming, rank and status, and funerary practices. Gender inferiority is clearly manifest in the marriages I describe below.

The Hierarchy of Women in Rulers' Households

The women of elite households during the Spring and Autumn period consisted of primary and secondary wives, concubines, and maids. All but maids served as socially approved sexual partners for their husband and/or master. This section focuses on these consorts. Particular attention is paid to polygyny; the recruitment of primary wives, secondary wives, and concubines; status changes and ranking of women within the houshold; and the implications of the mother's status for her children, especially sons.

In marked contrast to elite males of imperial China, men of the ruling elite of the Spring and Autumn period could have more than one primary wife at the same time (see table 1.1). A ruler's primary wife had the status of fu-jen . Because the ruler could have more than one primary wife, they were differentiated as principal primary wife (yuan-fei ), second primary wife (erh-fei ), and third primary wife (hsia-fei ) (literally, "first mate," "second mate," and "third mate"). The basis of this distinction among wives is not altogether clear, but the order of acquisition, perhaps after a ruler had been installed, appears to be a determinant, for taking a principal primary wife was a top priority for new rulers.

That polygynous marriage was practiced by rulers of states is unequivocally clear in the following three examples. First, in 720 Chuang Chiang, the barren principal primary wife of Duke Chuang of Wei, took the son he sired by Tai Wei to be her own son. Tai Wei was the younger sister of the duke's second primary wife, Li Wei, whose own son had died prematurely (TCCS 3:9b-10b [53, Yin 3]). Second, after Duke Wen was installed as ruler of Chin in 636, primary wife Tu Ch'i yielded rank to Chi Wei (TCCS 19a: 10a [315, Wen 6]). He had cohabited and fallen in love with Chi Wei after she was given to him as a female companion during his twelve-year exile among the Ti (TCCS 15:9a-b [25t, Hsi 23]). He evidently sent for and married her after gaining the rulership of Chin.[6] Finally, when the king of Ch'u passed through Cheng in 638, he was entertained by Mi-shih and Chiang-shih, primary wives of its ruler (TCCS 15:5a-6a [249, Hsi 22]).

Some polygynous marriages may have been motivated by the desire to obtain progeny or increase the pool of potential heirs.[7] Rulers also apparently contracted polygynous marriages to extend affinal ties and the associated political alliances; for example, all primary wives of rulers came from different states (see table 1.1).

Concubines provided another source of polygynous primary wives, usually because a concubine had become a ruler's favorite, or he wanted to make her son his successor, or both (TCCS 12:14a-16a [203-4, Hsi 4], 37:10b-


30

TABLE 1.1
Rulers and Multiple Primary Wives by Marriage

 

Husband

Wives

Year
B.C. a


State


Ruler


Reign


State

Clan Name


Name

722

Lu

Duke Hui

768-23

Sung

Tzu

Meng Tzu

720

Wei

Duke Chuang

757-34

Ch'i

Chiang

Chuang Chiang

720

     

Ch'en?

Wei

Li Wei

683-43

Ch'i

Duke Huan

685-43

Chou

Chi

Wang Chi

657-43

     

Ts'ai

Chi

Ts'ai Chi

643

     

Hsu

Ying

Hsu Ying

666

Chin

Duke Hsien

676-52

Chia

Chi

Chia Chi

666

     

Ta-jung

Chi

Hu Chi

666

     

Hsiao-jung

Yün

unknown

637-36

Chin

Duke Wen

636-28

Ti

Wei

Chi Wei

637

     

Ch'i

Chiang

Chiang-shih

636

     

Ch'in

Ying

Wen Ying

621

     

Tu

Ch'i

Tu Ch'i

638

Cheng

Duke Wen

659-28

Ch'u?

Mi

Mi-shih

       

Ch'i?

Chiang

Chiang-shih

613

Chu

Duke Wen

d. 613

Ch'i

Chiang

Ch'i Chiang

613

     

Chin

Chi

Chin Chi

609

Lu

Duke Wen

626-09

?

Ying

Ching Ying

534

Ch'en

Duke Ai

569-38

Cheng

Chi

Cheng Chi

534

     

?

?

unknown

534

     

?

?

unknown

SOURCE ; Tso-chuan .

NOTE: In the source, reference to a woman as yüan-fei implies other primary wives. Acquisition of primary wives by marriage is made explicit either in the text or through the use of verbs such as ch'i ("to [give as] wife"), ch'ü ("to take as wife"), and kuei ("to go to [the groom's home]") or implied by context.

This table does not include wives obtained through marriages that were contracted by a ducal son prior to his installation as ruler because such wives do not seem to have had the status of fu-jen .

a Year of mention in record.

12a [633-34, Hsiang 26], 60:19a-20b [1050, Ai 24]). Although promoting a concubine to the status of primary wife was done, it was not considered proper. The Mencius claims that in 651 this practice was made a punishable offense in an interstate covenant (MTCS 12b:1b [218]). When Duke Ai of Lu was going to install his favorite concubine as a primary wife in 471, he ordered the official in charge of ritual to offer the appropriate rite. The official asserted, however, that no such rite existed (TCCS 60:19a-b [1050, Ai 24]). Nevertheless, Duke Ai promoted her to primary wife because he intended to make her son his heir-apparent.


31

Secondary wives were acquired through a form of sororal polygyny (Granet 1920; Feng 46-51; Ruey 1958:14-15, 1959:249-51). Under the year 583 the Tso-chuan states: "Whenever the various rulers marry off their daughters, [ruling lineages] of the same clan name ying them. [Ruling lineages] of different clan names, however, do not" (TCCS 26:23a [447, Ch'eng 8]). On the first mention of this practice in the Ch'un-ch'iu in 675, the Kung-yang Commentary glosses: "What is ying ? When a vassal lord took a bride from one state, then two states [each] sent a female to her accompanied by chih and ti. Chih means the daughter of her elder brother. Ti means her younger sister. The vassal lord in one betrothal [acquired] nine females. The vassal lord did not marry again" (KYCS 8:1b-2a [97, Chuang 18]). Tu Yü (A.D. 222-84) says that the principal bride and both ying were accompanied by a niece and a younger sister, so that the total number of females came to nine (CCCS 12: 23b [183, Ch'eng 8]).

In actuality the provision of ying was not exactly as outlined here. Ruling lineages of different clan names did not send secondary brides,[8] as in the example above of Ch'i, clan name Chiang, sending a secondary bride to Lu, clan name Chi (CCCS 26:28a [449, Ch'eng 10]). More than two states could supply females, as when Wei, Chin, and Ch'i sent secondary brides to Lu between 583 and 581 for Po Chi, who was wed to Duke Kung of Sung (TCCS 26:23a [447, Ch'eng 8], 25a [448, Ch'eng 9]; CCCS 26:28a [449, Ch'eng 10]). And contrary to the observation by the Kung-yang Commentary , the presence of secondary brides in the household did not prevent additional marriages by rulers of states.

As the Tso-chuan evidence covering the Spring and Autumn period shows (table 1.2), the principal brides of rulers and officials of the ch'ing and tai-fu ranks were accompanied into marriage by a niece or younger sister, or both. There are no examples, however, of related lineages sending females to accompany the principal bride of a ch'ing or tai-fu . Apparently, only rulers were entitled to marry nine females at one time.

All of the females who accompanied the principal bride into marriage became secondary wives (even though theirs were not "secondary marriages" temporally speaking because they were married at the same time as the principal bride [Ruey 1958:15]). If the principal bride proved infertile or her offspring suffered premature death, reproduction became the main task of the secondary wives, a practice that ensured that a potential heir issued from the lineage of the principal bride, or, in the case of brides of rulers, a related lineage. Another important function for a secondary wife was to assume the role, but not the status, of the primary wife in the event of her death. For example, in 550 when the wife of Tsang Hsuan-shu of Lu died, Tsang "continued her role with her niece [chi shih i ch'i chih ]" (TCCS 35:18a [606, Hsiang 23]).[9] In the case of divorce or separation from the principal bride, the husband retained possession of his secondary brides (TCCS 58:26a-b [1018,


32

TABLE 1.2.
Secondary Brides of Rulers and Ch'ing or Tai-fu Officials

Year
B.C. a

Secondary
Bride

Principal Bride


Married to


Sonb

722

Sheng Tzu

Meng Tzu

Duke Hui of Lu

Y

720

Tai Wei

Li Wei

Duke Chuang of Wei

Y

675

(Lu girl)

(Wei girl)

Duke Hsuan? of Ch'en

 

660

Shu Chiang

Ai Chiang

Duke Chuang of Lu

Y

620

Sheng Chi

Tai Chi

Kung-sun Ao of Lu

Y

583

(Wei girl)

Po Chi

Duke Kung of Sung

 

582

(Chin girl)

Po Chi

Duke Kung of Sung

 

581

(Ch'i girl)

Po Chi

Duke Kung of Sung

 

554

Tsung-sheng Chi

Yen-i Chi

Duke Ling of Ch'i

Y

550

(Shou girl)

(Lu girl)

Tsang Hsuan-shu of Lu

Y

550

(Ch'i girl)

(Chin girl)

King Chu-fan of Wu

 

484

(Sung girl)

(Sung girl)

Ta-shu Chi of Wei

 

SOURCES : Ch'un-ch'iu and Tso-chuan .

NOTE : In the sources, secondary brides are revealed by the use of one or more of the following terms: chi-shih, chih, ti , or ying

a Year of mention in record.

b "Y" indicates that the secondary bride bore a son.

Ai 11]), thus preserving the affinal relationships established or renewed by the marriage.

Secondary brides did not have to be sent to the groom at the time of marriage. If the niece or younger sister who was selected to accompany the bride was not old enough at the time of the wedding, she could be sent later. This was the case with Shu Chi of Lu, who was sent to Chi five years after her elder sister, Po Chi (aka Kung Chi), was married to its ruler in 721 (TCCS 2:30a [42, Yin 2]; CCCS 4:3b-4a [71, Yin 7—text and Tu commentary]). The secondary wives from Wei, Chin, and Ch'i for Po Chi were provided to Lu over a period of three years from 583 to 581 (see table 1.2).

Concubines made up the third category of consorts of the ruling elite. In the Tso-chuan there is evidence of the practice of concubinage by the rulers of nine states, certainly an incomplete record because most references to concubinage are incidental to discussions of succession struggles or other unusual circumstances. Concubinage was not limited to rulers, however; the Tso-chuan also refers to the concubines of high officials.

Females became concubines in a variety of ways. A fairly common practice was for rulers to send females of their lineage, or for fathers to send their daughters, into concubinage (TCCS 7:11a [123, Huan 11], 10:13a [177, Chuang 28], 15:12b-13a [253, Hsi 23], 19a:9b [315, Wen 6], 26:6a-b [619,


33

Hsiang 25]). Mothers may also have sent their daughters to become concubines (TCCS 15:6a [249, Hsi 22]). Females were probably sold into concubinage (TCCS 41:24a [707, Chao 1]). The Tso-chuan provides no examples, however, of the purchase of concubines. Under fortunate circumstances a maid could become a concubine (TCCS 37:10b-12a [633-34, Hsiang 36—text and Tu commentary]). Finally, some women voluntarily joined the harems of the powerful (TCCS 45:18b- 19a [785-86, Chao 11 ]).

Rulers observed a truncated version of the marriage rites for some concubines, particularly those acquired from other powerful ruling lineages. When Duke P'ing of Chin secured Hsiao Chiang from Ch'i in 543, no reference is made to the betrothal request, but the rites of presenting betrothal gifts and fetching, escorting, and presenting the bride were performed. One can discern that Hsiao Chiang was not going to be a wife of Duke P'ing from the rank of the officer sent to fetch her and from that of the officer from Ch'i who escorted and presented the concubine to him (TCCS 43:3a-4a [719, Chao 2—text and commentaries]). Although some concubines may have been recruited in this fashion, most were acquired without any ceremony at all.

Duke Huan of Ch'i is reputed to have had many favored concubines. After noting that he had three barren wives, the Tso-chuan says that Duke Huan, "being fond of concubines, had many concubinal favorites. Six concubines were treated just like primary wives [fu-jen ]." All six appear to have been from or related to the ruling lineages of their native states. Four had the clan name of Chi, one Ying, and one Tzu. Each bore at least one son, four of whom eventually became dukes of Ch'i (TCCS 14:18a-b [237, Hsi 17]).[10]

The masters of concubines looked after them like the personal property that they evidently were. Prior to 558 Duke Hsien of Wei had a music instructor flogged three hundred times because he had whipped one of the duke's favorite concubines, whom he had been assigned to teach the lute (TCCS 32:14a-b [560, Hsiang 14]). And before the battle of Fu-chih in 594 Wei Wu-tzu of Chin became ill and ordered his son, Wei K'o, to marry off a favorite concubine who was without child. Then, when he became seriously ill, he instructed that she be buried alive with his corpse (TCCS 24:12a [409, Hsuan 15]), something he would not have ordered for his wife. Evidently some masters felt their proprietary rights over concubines extended beyond this life.

Wives and concubines were formally ranked within the household. In the state of Chin, for example, we know that at least nine ranks existed among consorts of the ruler because Huai Ying (aka Chen Ying), the concubine of Duke Wen, was ranked ninth (pan tsai chiu-jen ) (TCCS 19a:9b [315, Wen 6]). The consorts of Duke Mu of Cheng were evidently ranked, as the rank (pan ) of Kuei Wei was inferior to (ya ) that of Sung Tzu (TCCS 34:7a-b [587,


34

Hsiang 19]). Though the term pan does not appear in the Tso-chuan in reference to household women in other states, there is ample indirect evidence that they, too, were formally ranked.

The ranks of consorts were subject to change as the result of the addition of more primary wives or the promotion of sons. For example, among the women in the household of Duke Wen of Chin, Tu Ch'i yielded rank twice, once to Po Chi, who may have originally been a concubine and whose son was named heir-apparent, and again to Chi Wei, the captive girl mentioned earlier whom the Ti had given to Duke Wen during his exile among them. Tu Ch'i therefore ended up being ranked fourth (pan tsai ssu ). According to Tu Yü's calculations, Tu Ch'i's original rank was second (TCCS 19a:9a-10A [315, Wen 6]). In 636 a daughter whom Duke Wen had wed to a loyal follower also yielded rank to another Wife so that the latter's son could become her husband's heir (TCCS 15:16b-17a [254-55, Hsi 24]).

The distinctions among primary wives, secondary wives, and concubines were not simply matters of personal prestige. They also affected their children's status in the key event in the corporate life of state and lineage; namely, the selection of heirs and successors. The general rule was that the eldest son of the principal primary wife should be the first choice, then his full younger brothers in order of age, followed by half brothers by age. When Duke Hsiang of Lu died in 542, the son of Ching Kuei, a concubine from Hu, was selected to succeed him. But when this young man suddenly passed away, a half brother, the son of his mother's younger sister, was installed in his stead. Thereupon, an officer of Lu objected in vain saying:

When the heir-apparent dies, if he has a younger full brother (mu-ti ), then install him. If none, then install the eldest [half brother]. If their age is equal, then select the most worthy. If their sense of duty is equal, then divine [the selection]. This is the Way of antiquity. [Since the son of Ching Kuei] was not the legitimate heir (shih-ssu ), why must the son of her younger sister [be installed]? (TCCS 10:14b-15a [685-86, Hsiang 31])

Thus, since Duke Hsiang's heir-apparent had not been the son of his principal primary wife, the substitute heir need not be determined on the basis of closeness to him.[11]

Overturning the order of birthright was seen to undermine social stability and moral order (see Holmgren, chapter 2 of this volume, for a discussion of succession in later periods). Alluding to the struggle of a former concubine to get her son installed as heir-apparent, in 660 an officer of Chin is said to have quoted an ancient admonition to the Duke of Chou: "Treating concubines equal to queens, allowing external favorites to share political authority [with the chief minister], making the son of a favorite concubine (pi-tzu ) equal with the legitimate heir (ti ), and letting major walled towns grow to match the


35

capital, all of these give rise to chaos" (TCCS 11:14b [193, Min 2]). Concern about the ability of the son of a low-ranking woman to command the necessary respect is seen in Chao Tun's argument against installing Huai Ying's son as the ruler of Chin in 621: "Since she is lowly and her rank is ninth, what awe has her son?" (TCCS 19a:9a-10a [315, Wen 6]).[12]

Marriage Institutions

Among the ruling elite of the Spring and Autumn period, betrothals and weddings involved a series of rites. Although there is no complete record of the entire process on any one occasion, such rites include the following:

1. The tortoise shell and/or milfoil were consulted by the male and/or female side to divine the auspiciousness of initiating and/or continuing the betrothal and marriage process (TCCS 9:23b [163, Chuang 22], 14:8a-10b [232-33, Hsi 15], 36:2b-4a [617-18, Hsiang 25]).

2. Initial inquiry concerning the possibility of marriage would be initiated by either the male (TCCS 22:1b [367, Hsüan 5], 22:3a [377, Hsüan 6], 31:24b-25a [548, Hsiang 12], 43:11a (747, Chao 5]) or female side (4:6b [72, Yin 7]).

3. The marriage agreement was finalized either on the spot or at a later date (TCCS 4:6b [72, Yin 7], 31:24b-25a [548-49, Hsiang 12]).

4. The female side would respond to a request from the male side by offering a prospective bride for consideration (TCCS 43:11a [747, Chao 5]). (Requests for grooms from the female side, by contrast, were groom-specific.)

5. The groom's side had to make a formal petition for betrothal (TCCS 26:21b [446, Ch'eng 8], 51:6b-7a [887-88, Chao 25], 58:26b-27b [1018-19, Ai 11]).

6. The groom's side would then send betrothal gifts to the bride's family (TCCS 18:15b [304, Wen 2], 26:21b [446, Ch'eng 8], 41:14b-15a [702-3, Chao 1]).

7. Before fetching the bride, the groom reported to his key ancestors in their respective ancestral temples (TCCS 41:3a-b [697, Chao 1 ]).

8. The groom either sent a representative[13] or went himself[14] to fetch the bride from her home.

9. The bride was sent off by her parents (CCCS 6:3a [103, Huan 3—text and Tu commentary]; TCCS 4:6b [744, Chao 5]).[15]

10. A representative of the bride's family escorted the bride to the husband's home (TCCS 4:9b-10a [74, Yin 8], 6:4b-5a [104-5, Huan 3], 43:6b-13a [744-48, Chao 5]).


36

11. There the escort formally transferred the bride to her husband's family (TCCS 6:5a [104, Huan 3], CCCS 26:23b [447, Ch'eng 9], TCCS 26:25a [448, Ch'eng 9]).

12. In order for the marriage to be valid, the couple reported to the groom's ancestral temple before consummating their marriage (TCCS 4:9b-10a [74, Yin 8]).

13. After a trial period of about three months, the horse upon which the bride came was returned to her natal family, apparently as a sign that she was content to remain with her husband.

14. At some point after the marriage, the bride would also visit her parents to inquire about their welfare (CCCS 22:1a-b [376, Hsüan 5], TCCS 22:2a [376, Hsüan 5—text and commentaries]).[16]

The formal petition for betrothal (p'in ) was critical in this series of rites for it established the woman's status as that of primary wife. Without it, she was held to be merely a concubine (TCCS 27:1b [456, Ch'eng 11—text and Tu commentary]). Rituals performed for marriages between members of ruling houses were designed to reflect and reinforce interstate protocol. For example, a ruler was expected to depute officers of ch'ing rank to present betrothal gifts to the bride's family and to fetch the bride. Likewise, the ruler who was father of the bride was expected to send a person of appropriate rank to escort his daughter to her husband's state as follows:

When the daughter of a duke is married to [the ruler of] a state of equal rank, if she is an elder or younger sister [of the reigning duke], then a shang-ch'ing escorts her in order to show proper courtesy toward [her father] the former ruler. If she is the child of the duke, then a hsia-ch'ing escorts her. If the marriage is to the ruler of a greater state, even though she is the daughter of the duke, still a shang-ch'ing escorts her. If she is married to the Son of Heaven, then all those of ch'ing rank escort her. The duke does not himself escort her. If she is married to the ruler of a lesser state, then a shang tai-fu escorts her. (TCCS , 6:4b-5a [103-4, Huan 3])

Two types of prestations were associated with marriages among the ruling elite, namely, betrothal gifts and dowry. The former appear to have been presented by the groom's side to the family of the bride as part of the rite of initial inquiry and at the time of betrothal. Little is known about the goods that typically made up betrothal gifts. In 541 Kung-sun Hei of Cheng, who was seeking to claim his cousin's betrothed as his own, forced the woman's family to accept a fowl, perhaps to signal its favorable response to his overtures. When the woman's brother gave her the option of choosing between the two suitors, Kung-sun Hei came in the courtyard and "spread out his betrothal gifts" (pu ch'i pi [pi literally means "silk"]), while the woman looked on from her room (TCCS 41:14b-15a [702-3, Chao 1—text and Tu commentary]). In the event, the woman married her original fiancé,


37

who for his presentation had come into the courtyard in full battle dress, shot an arrow to the left and another to the right, vaulted into his chariot, and departed. Betrothal gifts had important symbolic functions, for the continuation or termination of the marriage process depended upon their reception (Liu Te-han 1976:48). Because betrothal gifts were received by the bride's family, they appear to be akin to bridewealth; however, there is no evidence that they became part of a "circulating pool of resources" used to acquire wives for brothers of the bride (Goody 1973:5).

The practice of direct dowry, whereby property was given to the bride by her kinsmen (ibid., 17), is clearly evident in many Western and Eastern Chou bronze inscriptions, which record a father giving (ying ) a bronze vessel to his daughter upon the occasion of her marriage.[17] From these inscriptions and the Tso-chuan a number of things can be learned about the outlays made by the bride's family in this period. Because of the political role of ruling-house marriages and the landholding system itself, land was not given as dowry. Bronze vessels, however, were gifts of considerable value. Servants were also sometimes given as dowry (TCCS 12:25b [205, Hsi 5]). The dowry provided by the bride's side could be very costly when a bride came from a ruling house. For example, the Tso-chuan reports that in 484 a high official in the state of Ch'en taxed grant lands (feng-t'ien ) in order to marry off the daughter of the duke (TCCS 18:23a-b [1077, Ai 11]).

The Western Chou rule of clan exogamy (Wang n.d.: 453-54) continued to be voiced in the Spring and Autumn period. In Tso-chuan dialogues it is usually stated as "male and female distinguish clan names [nan nü pien hsing ]," and it is mentioned only in contexts that make note of its violations (TCCS 15:11a-b [252, Hsi 23], 36:2b-4a [617-18, Hsiang 25], 38:25a-b [654, Hsiang 28], 41:24b [707, Chao 1]). Violation of this rule was thought to cause physiological problems for the perpetrators and any offspring that might be produced. For example, when Tzu-ch'an of Cheng was sent in 541 to the sickbed of Duke P'ing of Chin, who had four consorts with the same clan name as his own, he advised the duke to get rid of them:

I have heard that wives and concubines do not reach to the same clan name [as the husband]. If they do, their offspring do not mature. When their physical attraction is first exhausted, indeed, then their relationship gives birth to trouble. Because of that the gentleman despises it. Therefore, the record says, "If when buying a concubine, you do not know her clan name, then divine [the purchase] ." The ancients were wary about violating this rule. Male and female distinguishing clan names is a major regulation of ritual. (TCCS 41: 24a-b [707, Chao 1])[18]

In spite of perceptions that clan endogamy brought negative consequences, Chao ! reports that the rule was violated more often during the Spring and Autumn period than in any other era in ancient Chinese history


38

TABLE 1.3
Violations of Clan Exogamy

Clan Name

Male

Female's Lineage

Female's Status a

Chi

Duke Hsien of Chin

Chia

W

   

Ta Jung (Hu)

W

   

Li Jung

C

Chi

Duke P'ing of Chin

Wei

W

   

?

C

   

?

C

   

?

C

Chi

Duke Ting of Chin

Lu

W

Chi

Hsi Ch'ou of Chin

Kuan

W

Chi

Duke Chao of Lu

Wu

W

Chi

Shih Hsiao-shu of Lu

Kuan

W

Chi

Ta-shu Yi of Wei

Chin

W

Chi

(King of Wu)

Chin

W

Chiang

Ts'ui Chu of Ch'i

Tung-kuo

W

Chiang

Lu-p'u Kuei of Ch'i

Ch'ing

W

Mi

Wu Chü of Ch'u

Ch'u

W

SOURCE : Tso-chuan .

a W = wife; C = concubine.

(KYTK 31:646-47). The Tso-chuan records sixteen violations in the taking of wives and concubines (table 1.3). If secondary wives were factored into the above figures, the number of violations would be even higher.

Why was the rule of clan exogamy often ignored? In the fragmented polity and society of the period, clan ties had lost most of their relevance. In the pursuit of political alliances through intermarriage between ruling houses, political exigencies often outweighed exogamous considerations. In interstate relations clan ties provided no assurance of privileged treatment, as is evident in the complaint that when in 544 Duke P'ing of Chin fortified the capital of Chi, his mother's native state, he was assisting a state with a different clan name but had no pity for states bearing his own (TCCS 39:6b-7a [666-67, Hsiang 29]). At the individual level, self-interest overrode any concerns about endogamy. For example, in 545 Ch'ing She offered to marry a daughter to his retainer Lu-p'u Kuei, even though the Ch'ing and Lu-p'u lineages bore the same clan name of Chiang. A retainer of the prospective father-in-law criticized Lu-p'u Kuei for violating the rule on clan exogamy, but Lu-p'u countered that he had not taken the initiative in the match, and besides he stood to gain from it (TCCS 38:25a-b [645, Hsiang 28—text and Tu commentary]). By the Spring and Autumn period, the lineage had displaced the clan as the key kin group in the day-to-day affairs of state and society. In this environment, the rule of clan exogamy was ignored whenever


39

it became inconvenient, while lineage exogamy was strictly observed. Ruling houses, for example, never took brides from or gave daughters to members of segments of their own lineage or to members of lineages that had split off from it.

Chang Kwang-chih has suggested the existence of positive marriage rules in Shang and Chou China in the following hypothesis:

Within the framework of bilateral cross-cousin marriage, strong emphases were sometimes placed exclusively either on patrilateral (marrying father's sister's daughter [FZD] only) or the matrilateral (marrying the mother's brother's daughter [MBD] only) . . . the guiding principle of the shifting emphasis appears to be the political status of the intermarrying parties. Patrilateral cross-cousin marriages tended to take place between political equals, whereas matrilateral cross-cousin marriage tended to take place as a contributing factor to the delicate and dynamic balance of political power between lineages of unequal status. (1983:29)

While acknowledging that his own views on patrilateral cross-cousin marriage during the Shang are controversial, Chang argues for the existence of matrilateral cross-cousin marriage during the Eastern Chou, more particularly the Spring and Autumn period. His key points are, first, "intermarrying · states referred to each other as 'maternal uncle and sororal nephew states' [Chang's translation of chiu-sheng ], and this designation strongly suggests the probability that the relationship. . . was an ongoing one" (1983:29). Second, this term, "maternal uncle and sororal nephew states," applies to their respective states as states and not simply to particular rulers. Third, marriage exchanges tended not to be reciprocal, particularly from the perspective of lineage as opposed to clan. Fourth, there was a "difference in political status between the maternal uncle and sororal nephew states, and. . . the wife-receivers seem to have higher political and/or ritual status than the wife-givers" (Chang 1983:29-30). Anthropologists characterize this kind of marriage system as "asymmetrical" because women are always moving in one direction. Where prescriptive MBD marriage is practiced, it is found in stratified societies and results in perpetual marriage alliances between wife-givers and wife-receivers (Fox 1967:209-14).[19] My examination of Ch'un-ch'iu and Tso-chuan evidence does not bear out Chang's interpretation of marriage in the Spring and Autumn period.

For example, the most common usages of chiu ("father-in-law/mother's brother") and sheng ("sister's son/daughter's husband") imply sister exchange or reciprocal marriages (Granet 1930:156-60; Ch'en and Shyrock 1932:629-30; Feng 1937:43-46). Ruey Yih-fu notes a merging of consanguineous and affinal relatives in the uses of these terms, which he lists as

chiu : mother's brother, wife's father, husband's father

sheng : father's sister's son, mother's brother's son, wife's brother, sister's husband, daughter's husband, daughter's son


40

Ruey concurs that this phenomenon (i.e., the merging of consanguineous and affinal relatives in the usages of chiu and sheng ) indicates, and might be caused by, "the practice of cross-cousin marriage and, to a certain extent, of sister exchange marriages among the noble class at least" (1958:8-9). Chang's "framework of bilateral cross-cousin marriage" is based on this interpretation of these terms (1983:29), but he seeks to break new ground by showing that emphasis was placed on unilateral MBD marriages. Ruey argues convincingly, however, that chiu or sheng are difficult to distinguish because intermarriage between kin groups continued for generations (1959:245-46). Although the meanings of chiu and sheng can be used as evidence of the possibility of reciprocal cross-cousin marriage, they do not support the argument for one-way, nonreciprocal marriage. Depending on one's point of reference, the other party could be either chiu or sheng because of past or present bilateral marriage links.

Chang's second point, that these terms could refer to relations between states and not simply to particular rulers, can be accepted. Ruey has shown this was clearly the case because subsequent generations continued to use the terminology brought into play by a marriage, even though they had not renewed the marriage relationship (1959:252-54). But this practice negates the notion that these terms suggest ongoing relationships, or perpetual marriage alliances, between intermarrying states.

Ample evidence shows that many lineages intermarried. Thirty-five percent of marriages (twenty-nine of eighty-three) by rulers fall in this category, which I label "bilateral" instead of "reciprocal" because in the Spring and Autumn period there is no evidence of the creation of mutual marriage rights to females and obligations to continue to intermarry. Chang's conclusion is based primarily on data for marriages between Lu and Ch'i. Table 1.4 takes into account the marriages of rulers and their sons and grandsons in all of

TABLE 1.4
Bilateral Marriage Links among Ruling Lineages

Husband

 

Wives

Husband

 

Wives

Ch'en

=

Wei (1)

Wei

=

Ch'en (1)

Ch'en

=

Ts'ai (1)

Ts'ai

=

Ch'en (1)

Chi

=

Lu(4)

Lu

=

Chi(1)

Ch'i

=

Chou (2)

Chou

=

Ch'i (1)

Ch'i

=

Lu (2)

Lu

=

Ch'i (7)

Chin

=

Ch'in (3)

Ch'in

=

Chin (1)

Lu

=

Sung (2)

Sung

=

Lu (1)

Sung

=

Wei (1)

Wei

=

Sung (1)

NOTE : This table does not include bilateral marriages between Lu and a nonruling lineage, T'ang of Sung.


41

TABLE 1.5
Marriages by Social Status of Groom and Bride

 

To Daughters Of


Marriages By


Kings

Ruling Households


Ch'ing/Tai-fu


No Details

Kings of Chou

5

1

Ruling households

3

77

4

18

Ch'ing/tai-fu

19

22

1

SOURCES : Ch'un-ch'iu and Tso-chuan .

the major states. It shows that the ruling lineages listed both gave and accepted each other's daughters in marriage (numbers in parentheses indicate number of recorded wives): not only did brides move in both directions, but there is also no evidence for marriage with FZDs[20] and very little for MBDs.[21]

Chang's assertion that wife-receivers tend to hold higher political or ritual status than wife-givers does not stand up. For example, when the marriages of the ruling houses of Ch'i, Chin, Lu, and Wei are considered, the record shows that in one-way relationships as wife-receivers or as wife-givers, the political strength of these states was usually equal to or greater than those of their ruling-house marriage partners.[22] When interstate protocol—in which ritual status may have tended to outweigh political strength—at the time of marriage is taken into account, most of the bilateral marriage ties between the states listed in table 1.4 were contracted between ruling houses of equal status (even Chi and Lu). Of course, according to ritual status, the royal house of Chou was superior to its marriage partners, but it both sent daughters to and received brides from these lower-ranking houses. These is no evidence of a preference for one-way MBD marriage exchanges in which the wife-receiver always held higher status than the wife-giver. Within the gradations of ruling houses, superiors were giving women to and receiving women from inferiors, and equals were exchanging women among themselves.

In the Spring and Autumn period, marriages among the ruling elite tended to be class endogamous. For example, male members of ruling households usually chose spouses from other ruling households. Such marriages were, indeed, quite common (see table 1.5). But as revealed in the discussion above, considerable intermarriage took place among ranks from the same class, indicating that marriage, in its social implications, was a means of perpetuating class solidarity.

Heterogamous marriages between social classes also occasionally occurred. In addition to being married to men from their class, some daughters of rulers were married up to the king of Chou (who, after all, had to take women


42

from lower levels). A few ch'ing and tai-fu families married their daughters up to rulers, presumably as additional wives; one was pursued by the ruler of her state (TCCS , 10:22a [181, Chuang 28]) and the other, from a powerful ministerial lineage in a major state, was married to the ruler of a minor state (TCCS 48:22a [844, Chao 19]). Two marriages between sons of rulers and daughters of ch'ing and tai-fu involved sons who were not in line for the rulership.[23] Kings of Chou, who were without peer in the realm, married their daughters to rulers of select states (TCCS , 8:4a-b [137, Chuang 1]; 9:3b [153, Chuang 11]; 20:5b [349, Wen 16]; also CCCS , 9:la [152, Chuang 1]). Even more common in the sources are unequal matches involving daughters of ruling households who married down. Eleven of sixteen such marriages, however, involved unusual circumstances;[24] so hypogamous marriages between ruling households and ch'ing and tai-fu lineages may not have been as common as these figures suggest (for marriages of imperial daughters in later periods, see Chaffee, chapter 4, and Rawski, chapter 5, in this volume).

If ruling-house marriages were not structured by patterns of accepting wives from lower-ranking ruling houses and giving them to higher ones or vice-versa, what did govern marriage choices? From my reading of the sources, these marriages, particularly when contracted by the ruler himself, were dictated by political considerations. From the points of view of both the groom's and the bride's side, they were political marriages. As a rule, they were not the product of perpetual marriage alliances that had to be renewed in every generation (cf. Goody 1973:35-36). When Lu experienced a famine in 666, its ruler was told that the way to obtain aid from neighboring states was to "secure the trust of the rulers, compound it through marriage, and enhance it through covenants" (KY 4:3a [111, Lu Yü shang ]). Lü Hsiang of Chin echoed these remarks when he observed that the good relationship between deceased rulers Duke Hsien of Chin and Duke Mu of Ch'in had been extended by way of covenant and enhanced through marriage; namely, that of the daughter of Duke Hsien to Duke Mu in about 655 (TCCS 27:1 la-b [461, Ch'eng 13—text and Tu commentary]). The Tso-chuan states that marriage and the maintenance of good relations with affines were of the first order of importance in the affairs of a new ruler (TCCS 18:15b [304, Wen 21 ]). Rulers received brides from and gave daughters to other ruling houses to seal agreements, signal friendly intentions, extend recognition, and, most important, secure the support and protection of affines in the interstate, and sometimes domestic, struggle for power and survival. Despite the incompleteness of the marriage record in the Ch'un-ch'iu and Tso-chuan , it is evident that wives were received from and given to many different lineages (see table 1.6).

The major states of Ch'i and Chin and the less powerful states of Lu and Wei show a pattern of wide geographic dispersal of marriages. Chin provides a good example of how the geographic span of ruling-house marriages was influenced by interstate politics. Duke Hsien (r. 676-52), who ruled when


43

TABLE 1.6
Affinal Relations of Ruling Lineages

State

Received Wives From

Gave Wives To

Ch'en

Cheng, Chou, I-shih , Ts'ai, Wei

Cheng, Hsi, Ts'ai, Wei

Cheng

Ch'en, Chiang, Shen

Ch'en, Sung

Ch'i

Chi-shih , Chou, Hsu, Lu, Sung, Ts'ai, Yen

Chin, Chou, Chu, Lu, Wei

Ch'in

Chin

Chin, Ch'u

Chin

Chi, Ch'i, Chia, Ch'in, Hsiao Jung, Liang, Ta Jung, Ti, Tu, Wei

Ch'in, Chu, Ch'u, Lu, Wu

Chou

Ch'en, Chi, Ch'i, Ti

Ch'en, Sung

Ch'u

Cheng, Chin, Ch'in, Teng, Wei, Yuan

Ts'ai

Lu

Chi, Ch'i, Chu, Mou, Shen, Shou, Sung, Tang-shih , Wu

Chi, Chi, Ch'i, Sung, Tang-shih , Tseng, Yen

Sung

Cheng, Chou, Lu, Wei

Ch'i, Lu, Wei

Ts'ai

Ch'u

Ch'i

Wei

Ch'en, Ch'i, Sung, Tung-kuo-shih

Ch'en, Chin, Ch'u, Hsu, Sung

SOURCES : Ch'u-ch'iu and Tso-chuan .

NOTE : This table does not include (1) the marriage of King Wu of Ch'u to Hsi Wei, who was the wife of the ruler of Hsi and a woman from Ch'en, whom he took as wife after destroying the state of Hsi in 680; (2) marriages for which the state or the lineage name of the spouse is unknown; and (3) concubines who were elevated to the status of wife.

Chin was building its regional power base, received brides from the ruling houses of the weaker nearby states of Chia and the barbarian Ta Jung and Hsiao Jung, presumably to secure the peace and obtain their allegiance, and he gave a daughter to Ch'in (whom Chin was not strong enough to dominate) in order to firm up friendship with this rival power. Duke Wen (r. 636-28), who had received a "courtesy" bride from the ruling house of Ch'i while in exile as a ducal son, was installed as ruler of Chin through the intervention of Duke Mu of Ch'in. His first act as ruler was to take a daughter of the latter as principal wife. (Although Duke Mu had earlier received a half sister of Duke Wen as wife, this marriage should be interpreted in its political context rather than as an obligatory marital exchange.) Under the leadership of Duke Wen, Chin took the role of hegemon away from Ch'i, establishing itself as one of the most powerful states of the Spring and Autumn period. The rulers of Chin, now hegemons, established marriage ties with the rulers of more distant rival states. In 550 Chin sent a ruler's daughter to the state of Wu, a newcomer to power politics (TCCS 35:9b [602, Hsiang 23]). Duke P'ing received a bride from Ch'i in 539 (TCCS 42:8b-9b [721-22, Chao 2]). In 537 Duke P'ing gave a daughter to King Ling of Ch'u, the chief competitor of Chin, who had requested the match because


44

Ch'u perceived itself to be in a weaker military position (TCCS 43:11 a [747, Chao 5]). As instruments of interstate politics, marriages followed shifting alliances among the competing states.

The ruling elite recognized both specific and diffuse obligations to affines and matrilateral kin. Mourning rites were observed for deaths of atones (TCCS 35:11a [603, Hsiang 23]; 45:6a [779, Chao 9]). One ruler aided in building or repairing defensive walls around the capital city of his mother's home state (TCCS 29:6b [666, Hsiang 29]). The marriage of the ruler of Yü to the daughter of the chief minister of Sung bore fruit in 523 when her brother persuaded the duke of Sung to send an army against the state of Chu because it had attacked Yü in the previous year (TCCS 48:17b-18a [842, Chao 18], 22a [844, Chao 19]). Duke Mu of Ch'in installed two of his wife's half brothers, Duke Hui and Duke Wen, as rulers of Chin (TCCS 13:13a-14a [220, Hsi 9]; 15:16a [254, Hsi 24]). A speech of Lü Hsiang, breaking relations with Ch'in in 579, enumerates many more instances of how Chin and Ch'in had helped each other in dealing with other states and settling succession problems since the time of Duke Hsien and Duke Mu (TCCS 27:11b-12a [461, Ch'eng 13]).[25]

Much of the responsibility for achieving the goals of a political alliance based on or reinforced by marriage fell to the woman who was transferred by the marriage. From the perspective of the ruling house that gave its daughter to another ruling house in marriage, the woman was to become its agent in her new home. In the short run she was to use her influence to look after the interests of the state ruled by her natal lineage and in the long run to produce a line of heirs who would be amenable to maintaining friendly and supportive relations with it (for later periods, see Holmgren, chapter 2 of this volume). These short- and long-term objectives must have accelerated the practice of sending a niece and a younger sister of the principal bride as secondary brides who were there to further buttress affinal and matrilateral relations as secondary wives and childbearers.

After a daughter married out as a primary wife, she would occasionally return to visit her parents. She visited her natal family to inquire about the welfare of her parents after her marriage (TCCS 10:10b [175, Chuang 27]), to present her new child (CCCS 12:16b [204, Hsi 5], and sometimes to request a bride for her son (CCCS 16:1a [262, Hsi 25]; 17:8a [286, Hsi 31]). She could also return home if rejected by her husband or his lineage (TCCS 10:10b [175, Chuang 27—text and Tu commentary]). Parents continued to be concerned about the welfare of daughters who married out. For example, in 613 Duke Wen of Lu asked Ch'i to return a daughter, who had been married to Duke Chao, because her son had been assassinated immediately upon assuming the rulership. Although he claimed he wanted to punish her, Duke Wen's real intent was to protect her (TCCS 19b:l5a-b [335, Wen 14], 18a [336, Wen 14], 25a [340, Wen 15]).


45

For their part, married women retained a strong loyalty toward and acted as agents for their natal lineages. If forced to choose between her husband and father, the married daughter was expected to put her father first. This is revealed in the resolution of the dilemma faced by Yung Chi, the daughter of Chi Chung, who was the most powerful officer in Cheng in 594. When her husband was ordered to assassinate her father and she became aware of it, she went to her mother for advice and asked, "Which one is dearer, husband or father?" Her mother responded with a rhetorical question, "Any man can be a husband, [but] a father is simply unique. How can they be compared?" Satisfied, she tipped off her father, and he killed her husband to save his own life (TCCS 7:20a-b [127, Huan 15]; see also TCCS 38:27a-b [655, Hsiang 28]). Wives of rulers intervened in government affairs in behalf of their native states, as when the wife of Duke Mu of Ch'in secured the release of her captured half brother, Duke Hui of Chin, in 645 (TCCS 14:6a-7a [231-32, Hsi 15]) and the widowed wife of former Duke Wen talked his successor into freeing three captured generals from her home state of Ch'in in 627 (TCCS 17:15b-16a [290, Hsi 33]). Besides looking after the interests of their native state in circumstances such as these, married daughters continued to have an interest in events at home. Mu Chi, the wife of Duke Mu of Ch'in, for example, tried to influence internal affairs of her natal lineage, the ducal house of Chin, when her husband installed her half brother I-wu as ruler of Chin in 650 (TCCS 14:2b [229, Hsi 15]).

Despite the political importance of the affinal ties created by marriage, divorce was permitted. Marriages were sometimes terminated by one of the spouses for personal reasons (TCCS 2:30a [42, Yin 2]), but divorces could also be forced by kinsmen seeking to maintain harmony within the lineage or family (TCCS 19a:16a-b [318, Wen 7]), out of personal animosity (TCCS 27:1b-2a [456, Ch'eng 11]), or to obtain certain political objectives (TCCS 27:2a-b [456, Ch'eng 11]; 58:26a-b [1018, Ai 11]). Nonkinsmen could also force the termination of a marriage to promote their own interests. For example, in 558 the officers of Cheng set the stage for taking action against a leading member of the T'u lineage by sending the wife of one of his kinsmen back to her natal lineage in Chin, thereby breaking the claim of the T'u lineage to assistance from affines in a powerful state (TCCS 32:26b [566, Hsiang 15—text and Tu commentary]).

Just as the implications of marriage went beyond the bride and groom to the relations between their respective lineages and, in the case of ruling houses, their states, divorce was an equally far-reaching matter because it potentially involved these relationships. I say "potentially" because a wife could be divorced without severing the affinal tie established with her lineage if the proper procedure were followed. Two examples of this process involve the ruling houses of Chi and Lu. In 616 when Duke Huan of Chi appeared for the first time in the court of Lu, the Tso-chuan says Duke Wen acceded to his


46

request to break off his relationship with Shu Chi while preserving marital relations with the ruling house of Lu (ch'ing chueh Shu Chi erh wu chueh hun ). In the second month of the same year, she passed away (TCCS 19:5a-b [330, Wen 12]). When Duke Huan came to court in Lu again in 587, the Tso-chuan states that "it was for the purpose of returning Shu Chi [another Lu bride]" (TCCS 26:6b [438, Ch'eng 4]). Duke Ch'eng of Lu evidently agreed, for Shu Chi moved back the following year (CCCS 26:8a [439, Ch'eng 5]). After she died, possibly by committing suicide, in 583 (TCCS 26:23a [447, Ch'eng 8]), Duke Huan agreed to come and take her body back to Chi for proper burial, as if she were still his wife (TCCS 26:24b [447, Ch'eng 9]). Under ordinary circumstances a divorced woman was no longer regarded as kin (TCCS 8:3b [137, Chuang 1]) and thus not entitled to funeral rites or mourning by her former affines.

Conclusion

In this chapter I have focused on marriage in the ruling elite, especially the ruling households, of the Spring and Autumn period. Particular attention has been paid to the ways that marriage practices were related to the political and social organization of the period. I shall conclude with some observations on the marriage system and its continuities and discontinuities in later periods.

The political, social, economic, and marriage systems, as well as kinship terminology, of the Spring and Autumn period exhibit most of the characteristics that Jack Goody has associated with dowry systems in Eurasian society (1973, 1976). The polity in this period was complex, with large states and highly stratified local societies; the economy was based on intensive agriculture including the animal-drawn plough; in-marriage was practiced in the form of class endogamy; premarital sex was proscribed (Chia 1980:23); and kinship terminology distinguished siblings from cousins (for the latter, see EYCS 4:14a-19a [61-64]). The practice of polygyny, however, is an important exception to Goody's formulation. The coexistence and convergence of polygyny and dowry in the Spring and Autumn period are explicable with reference to the political and social context of the time in which politics, not economics, determined social status and marriage strategies. Polygyny was used as a diplomatic tool by the lineages of both bride and groom. Dowry helped to confirm the primary-wife status of the principal bride of rulers and heads of patrilineages and to secure her loyalty to her natal state and/or lineage.

In the Spring and Autumn period the patrilineage was the exogamous kin group. No positive or prescriptive marriage rule was followed. Although patrilateral or matrilateral cross-cousin marriages may have occurred, there is no evidence that they were frequent or preferred. Bilateral marriages were


47

more common, but again there is no evidence that they were reciprocal between cross-cousins or based on perpetual marriage alliances. Mate selection had to be flexible in order to attain political objectives.

I would now like to highlight some continuities with marriage practices in later periods of Chinese history. Here it is useful to distinguish between continuities in marriage practices in general and those associated with the ruling elite. As to the former, significant continuity exists in the overall ritual sequence, which shows similarities from the rulers of the Spring and Autumn period to ordinary people of relatively recent times. Elite practices and their codification in ritual texts have served as guides to marriage since Han times (Dull 1978:34-51). Marriage prestations in the form of betrothal gifts from the groom's side and dowry from the bride's side have continued with varying degrees of emphasis. Concubinage continued unabated through most later periods, but usually as an adjunct of monogamy rather than polygyny. Also noteworthy is the continuing tie between women and their natal families. Continuities with later imperial marriage practices can be discerned in the ordering of women in harems into several ranks, in the preference for sons by a wife for heir-apparent or successor, and even in the promotion of the mother of a proposed heir to improve appearances (see the chapters by Holmgren and Rawski here).

Exogamy has been a general feature of marriage practices from the earliest times to the present. Subtle historical differences, however, should not be overlooked. Prior to the Eastern Chou era the rule of surname exogamy applied to those who shared the same hsing , or clan name. In the Spring and Autumn period the patrilineage was the exogamous unit; so those with the same shih , or lineage name, did not intermarry. By Han times hsing and shih had become synonymous, and the unit of exogamy had constricted further to include only those descended from more recent common ancestors; consequently, the rule of surname exogamy could be violated, but one could not marry within his or her natal tsung (Dull 1978:29-30; Liu Tseng-kuei 1980: 10-11). In later periods, however, the scope of exogamy was officially extended to all those with the same surname.

Another important shift in marriage practices took place after the Spring and Autumn period. Later emperors, particularly in Chinese regimes, married within their realm, unlike rulers during the Spring and Autumn period, which may explain the absence of powerful consort families in the management of state and lineage affairs at that time. By contrast, most dynastic regimes were constantly faced with problems created by powerful consort families and influential court women (see Holmgren's chapter).

The two most striking discontinuities with marriage practices in later periods are found in taking more than one wife at a time and in the principal bride's family and lineage sending secondary brides. In the multistate system of the Spring and Autumn period, general polygyny was used by rulers as a


48

survival strategy to multiply political alliances and extend affinal relations, while sororal polygyny served the political interests of the bride's family, lineage, and state by increasing the likelihood of producing a successor to the bride's husband who would be amenable to maintaining friendly relations with his mother's family. These political exigencies did not exist in the imperial period. The power of affines presented more significant problems than hostile regimes on the outside. Taking additional wives would have compounded those problems.

Perhaps a more fundamental reason, however, for these discontinuities and the relative insignificance of dowry in the early imperial period (see chapter 3 by Ebrey) is the sweeping social and political changes that accelerated in the Warring States period and culminated in the formation of the empire. The upper echelons of the ruling elite were gradually swept away as powerful ministerial lineages rose to displace their ruling houses, and states were eliminated one by one in the process of unification. Officials of shih rank moved to the top of the official hierarchy, then major reforms, such as those instituted by Shang Yang in Ch'in (Li 1977:37-40), altered the system of ranks and fundamentally changed the status system, thereby depriving the old aristocracy of its prerogatives and enabling commoners to rise to high rank and status. By the time of the formation of the empire, the old aristocracy and its more extravagant ways had been swept away, and a new elite of commoner background was in place with its more modest customs and practices.


54

Glossary

chenginline image

ch'iinline image

chi-shihinline image

chi-shih i ch'i chihinline image

chiang-sunginline image

ch'iehinline image

chih (elder brother's daughter) inline image

chih (to escort to. the final destination) inline image

chih fu-jeninline image

ch'inginline image

ch'ing chueh Shu Chi erh wu chueh huninline image

chiuinline image

chiu-shenginline image

ch'üinline image

erh-feiinline image

feiinline image

feng-t'ieninline image

fu-jeninline image

hsi (to amuse oneself) inline image

hsi (to play) inline image

hsia-ch'inginline image

hsia-feiinline image

hsia-guoinline image

hsinginline image

kueiinline image

mu-tiinline image

nan nü pien hsinginline image

inline image

paninline image

pan tsai chiu jeninline image

pan tsai ssuinline image

painline image

paoinline image

peiinline image

piinline image

pi-tzuinline image

pininline image

p'ininline image

pu ch'i piinline image

shang-ch'inginline image

shang-tai-fuinline image

shenginline image

shih (officer) inline image

shih (lineage name) inline image

shih-ssuinline image

sunginline image

ta-kuoinline image

tai-fuinline image

tanginline image

tanginline image

ti (younger sister) inline image

ti (legitimate heir) inline image

t'iaoinline image

t'unginline image

tsunginline image

tz'u-kuoinline image

yainline image

yaoinline image

yiinline image

yininline image

yinginline image

yuinline image

yuan feiinline image

References

Primary Sources

CCSTP Ch'un-ch'iu shih-tsu p'uinline image, comp. Ch'en Hou-yao inline image. In Shao-wu Hsu-shih ts'ung-shuinline image.

CCTCC Ch'un-ch'iu Tso-chuan chuinline image, comp. Yang Po-chün inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1981.

CCTK Ching-chi tsuan-kuinline image. Taipei: Wen wen, 1967.

CCTSP Ch'un-ch'iu ta-shih piaoinline image, comp. Ku Tung-kao inline image. In Huang-Ch'ing ching-chieh hsu-pieninline image, vol. 3.


55

EYCS Erh-ya chu-shuinline image. SSCCS edition.

FY Fang-yeninline image, by Yang Hsiung inline image, with commentary by Kuo P'u inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu chen-pen pieh-chi inline image edition. Taipei: Commercial Press, 1975.

ILCS I-li chu-shuinline imageSSCCS edition.

KY T'ien-sheng ming-tao pen kuo yüinline image, commentary by Wei Chao inline image. Photolithic reprint edition. Taipei: I-wen, 1969.

KYCS Kung-yang chu-shuinline image. SSCCS edition.

KYSC Hsin-shih piao-tien kuang-ya shu-chenginline image , punctuated by Chan Hong-kam inline image. Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1978.

KYTK Kai-yü ts'ung-k'aoinline image, by Chao Yi inline image. Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1957. Based on Chan-i-t'anginline image edition, 1790.

MTCS Meng-tzu chu-shuinline image. SSCCS edition.

SSCCS Shih-san-ching chu-shuinline image, comp. Juan Yuan inline image. Photolithic reprint edition. Taipei: I-wen, 1973.

TCCS Tso-chuan chu-shuinline image, comp. K'ung Ying-ta inline image. SSCCS edition.

TCHC Tso-chuan hui-chien inline image, comp. Takezoe Koko inline image. Taiwan: n.p., n.d.

YCCWCL Yin-Chou chin-wen chi-luinline image, ed. Hsu Chung-shu inline image. Szechwan: Jen-min, 1984.

Secondary Works

Chang, K. C. 1976. Early Chinese Civilizations: Anthropological Perspectives . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

———. 1983. Art, Myth, and Ritual: The Path to Political Authority in Ancient China . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Chao, Lin. N.d. Marriage, Inheritance, and Lineage Organization in Shang-Chou China . Taipei: I-chih.

Ch'en, T. S., and J. K. Shyrock. 1932. "Chinese Relationship Terms." American Anthropologist 34:623-69.

Ch'i Ssu-ho inline image. 1981. Chung-kuo shih t'an-yeninline image (Inquiries into Chinese history). Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü.

Chia Shih-heng inline image. 1980. "Yin-Chou fu-nü sheng-huo ti chi-ke mien" inline image (Some aspects of women's life during Yin and Chou dynasties). Ta-lu tsa-chih 60.5:7-39.

Creel, Herlee G. 1970. The Origins of Statecraft in China . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Dull, Jack. 1978. "Marriage and Divorce in Han China: A Glimpse at Pre-Confucian Society." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Feng, Han-yi. 1937. The Chinese Kinship System . Reprinted from Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 2:2 (July 1937). Taipei: Southern Materials Center, Inc.

Fox, Robin. 1967. Kinship and Marriage . Middlesex, Eng.: Penguin.

Goody, Jack. 1973. "Bridewealth and Dowry in Africa and Eurasia." In Bridewealth


56

and Dowry , by Jack Goody and S. J. Tambiah. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1976. Production and Reproduction: A Comparative Study of the Domestic Domain . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Granet, Marcel. 1920. La polygynie sororale et le sororat dans la Chine féodale . Paris: Editions Ernest Leroux.

———. 1930. Chinese Civilization . London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

Hsu, Cho-yun. 1965. Ancient China in Transition: An Analysis of Social Mobility, 722-222B.C . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

———. 1984. Hsi-Chou shihinline image (A history of the Western Chou dynasty). Taipei: Lien-ching.

Leach, E. R. 1954. Political Systems of Highland Burma: A Study of Kachin Social Structure . London: G. Bell and Sons.

Li Hui inline image. 1954. "Chung-kuo ku-tai ti shou-chi-hun" inline image (Levirate marriage in ancient China). Ta-lu tsa-chih 9.4:17-20.

Li Tsung-t'ung inline image. 1954. Chung-kuo ku-tai she-hui-shihinline image (Social history of ancient China). 2 vols. Taipei: Chung-hua wen-hua.

Li Hsueh-ch'in inline image. 1984. Tung-Chou yü Ch'in-tai wen-minginline image (The civilization of the Eastern Chou and Ch'in dynasties). Peking: Jen-min.

Li Yu-ning, ed. 1977. Shang Yang's Reforms and State Control in China . White Plains.

Liu Po-chi inline image. 1962. Ch'un-ch'iu hui-meng cheng-chihinline image (Government by alliance during the Spring and Autumn period). Taipei: Chung-hua ts'ung-shu.

Liu Te-han inline image. 1976. Tung-Chou fu-nü sheng-huoinline image (The life of women during the Eastern Chou). Taipei: Hsueh-sheng.

Liu Tseng-kuei inline image. 1980. Han-tai hun-yin chih-tuinline image (The institution of marriage during the Han dynasty). Taipei: Hua-shih.

Liu Tse-hua inline image et al. 1979. Chung-kuo ku-tai shihinline image (A history of ancient China). Peking: Jen-min.

Lü Ssu-mien inline image. 1941; reprint, 1962. Hsien Ch'in shihinline image (A history of pre-Ch'in China). Hong Kong: T'ai-ping.

Ruey, Yih-fu. 1958. "The Similarity of the Ancient Chinese Kinship Terminology to the Omaha Type." Bulletin of the Department of Archaeology and Anthropology (Academia Sinica) 12:1-18.

———inline image. 1959. "Shih sheng-chiu chih kuo" inline image ("Nephew and uncle" states: an interpretation). Bulletin of the Institute of History and Philology (Academia Sinica) 30.1:237-58.

Sun Yueh inline image. 1931; reprint, 1976. Ch'un-ch'iu shih-tai ti shih-tsuinline image (Influential clans of the Spring and Autumn period). Ching-mei.

T'ang Ming-sui inline image. 1982. Chung-kuo ku-tai she-hui ching-chi shihinline image (Social and economic history of ancient China). Honan: Chung-chou.

Thatcher, Melvin P. 1977-78. "A Structural Comparison of the Central Governments of Ch'u, Ch'i, and Chin." Monumenta Serica 33:140-41.

———. 1985. "Central Government of the State of Ch'in in the Spring and Autumn Period." Journal of Oriental Studies 23.1:29-53.


57

Walker, Richard Louis. 1953. The Multi-state System of Ancient China . Hamden, Conn.: Shoestring Press.

Wang Kuo-wei inline image. 1973. Kuan-t'ang chi-lininline image (Collected writings of Kuan-t'ang). Reprint. Hong Kong: Chung-hua shu-chü.

Yang Hsi-mei inline image. 1963a. "Kuo-yü Huang-ti erh-shih-wu tzu te hsing ch'uan-shuo ti fen-hsi shang p'ien" inline image (A study of the legend of Huang-ti's descendants in the Kuo-yü ). Bulletin of the Institute of History and Philology (Academia Sinica) 34.2:627-48.

———. 1963b. "Lun 'Chin-yü' Huang-ti ch'uan-shuo yü Ch'in Chin lien-yin ti ku-shih" inline image (On the legend of Huang-ti in the "Chin-yü" and stories of marriages of alliance between Ch'in and Chin). Ta-lu tsa-chih 26.6:1-6.

Yang K'uan inline image. 1980. Chan-kuo shihinline image (History of the Warring States). 2d ed. Shanghai: Jen-min.


58

Two
Imperial Marriage in the Native Chinese and Non-Han State, Han to Ming

Jennifer Holmgren

For about half its recorded history, China has been ruled either in part or wholly by peoples of non-Chinese (non-Han) origin. Indeed, in the last thousand years only two of six imperial families were of local or native Chinese background. The others came from the steppe/Manchurian area to the north of China proper (see the Chronology). One aspect of the cultural interaction during such periods of conquest has long fascinated both Chinese and Western scholars—namely, the influence of those northern cultures on Chinese attitudes toward women. It is often suggested, for example, that the high political profile of imperial wives and princesses during the early T'ang period (seventh-eighth centuries) was the result of the relatively high status of women in steppe society and their consequent involvement in court politics during the preceding conquest era. In a similar vein, the well-documented concern of the founder of the Ming dynasty to restrict the power of imperial wives in the fourteenth century has been seen as a reaction against the authority assumed by such women in the preceding Mongol-Yuan era. Although firmly entrenched in both the scholarly and the popular imagination, this hypothesis has never been seriously tested; it is based on accounts of curious lives and extraordinary events rather than on an examination of the principles behind continuity and change. This chapter seeks to redress that situation by looking at the structure underlying attitudes to imperial marriage and the political role of the emperor's wife in the native Chinese and non-Han state.

The first section of the chapter begins by establishing the principles behind events commonly encountered in the historical narrative of the native state from Han times through to the end of the Ming dynasty (206 B. C .-A. D .). 1644). For our purposes, the most illustrative events include disputes between the emperor and the bureaucracy over the appointment of an empress;


59

accusations that imperial relatives were conspiring to usurp the throne; dethronements by dowager empresses; complaints about the conduct of imperial princesses; harem disputes leading to the murder of imperial wives and their offspring; and so forth. These "structural principles" are then used to evaluate the changes within and across individual native regimes. I shall show that some conditions previously thought to be unique to one particular period (and thus probably the result of foreign influence or externally derived ideas) are easily explained without reference to the non-Han state.

The second section of the chapter demonstrates the variety and political ingenuity of marriage systems designed by the leaders of the conquest dynasties. For reasons that shall become apparent, each non-Han regime is discussed separately. Three states, whose histories span both sides of the T'ang-Sung transition era—the T'o-pa state of Wei (A. D . 399-534), the Ch'i-tan (Khitan) Liao dynasty (A. D . 916-1122), and the Mongol empire (c. A. D . 1200-1368)—have been selected for investigation. The final section discusses how an analysis of the non-Han condition throws new light on the question of continuity and change in Chinese society and then summarizes the political status of different sets of imperial kin in each of the systems described

In this essay three main categories of the emperor's kin are distinguished—paternal, maternal, and sororal. The term "paternal kin" covers male and female relatives in the male line (e.g., the emperor's father's siblings, his father's brothers' offspring, his own siblings, his brother's offspring, etc.), while that of "maternal kin" (matrilateral kin) embraces relationships established through the mother (e.g., the emperor's mother's parents and her siblings and their offspring). The term "sororal relative" covers relationships established through the marriages of princesses (the emperor's paternal aunts [FZ], sisters, and daughters); i.e., it refers to the offspring of these women, their husbands, husbands' parents, and siblings (wife-taking families).

This chapter outlines the social and political inequalities between the different sets of women whose marriages provided the essential building blocks for political activity at court and highlights some unexpected features of the unequal relations between these women and the various males (including the emperor) with whom they were closely associated. Where non-Han states are concerned, the chapter also touches on the question of marriage and ethnic inequality. The theme of inequality between imperial clans-women and their spouses is addressed more broadly by John W. Chaffee in his chapter on the Sung, while that of marriage and ethnic inequality is taken up again by Evelyn S. Rawski in her chapter on the Ch'ing.


60

The Native Chinese State

In general, laws and regulations relating to marriage in the larger society also prevailed at the imperial level of the native Chinese state. Some were already in place in preimperial times (see Thatcher's chapter in this volume) and may be summarized as follows: (1) surname exogamy (TL 14:262-63; SHT 14:218-19; ML 6:16; Feng 1948:33-46); (2) serial monogamy with concubinage (TL 13:255; SHT 13:214; TML 13:275; Ch'ü 1972:46); (3) the wife as titular or legal mother to all offspring (Tjan 1949:260; Watsons chapter in this volume); (4) a ban on demoting wives to the rank of concubine and on elevating concubines to the status of wife (SHT 13:214-15; ML 6:9-10; TML 13:275-76; Ebrey 1986); and (5) a ban on cross-generational alliance (TL 14:263; SHT 14:218-19; TML 14:287; Ch'ü 1961:94-95). At the imperial level, the emphasis on monogamy meant that the title of empress went to the woman who had held the position of wife before her husband's accession to the throne. It also meant that there could be only one empress at any one time (Chung 1981:147) and that she was the titular mother of the next ruler whether or not she herself was his biological mother. The rule of surname exogamy meant that no matter how distant the relationship, members of the ruling family could not marry imperial clansmen but had to marry out and downward. Finally, although cousins of a different surname might marry (MBD/FZD), unions between heirs to the throne and their aunts (MZ/FZ) or nieces (FDD/MDD) were forbidden (see n. 3). These restrictions were but one of many conditions preventing individual families from gaining an exclusive permanent hold on marriage relations with the throne.[1]

There were other, more general customs and practices that conditioned marriage both in the larger society and at the imperial level. For example, married women continued ties to their natal kin (Ebrey 1981; the chapters by Thatcher and Watson in this volume); in the event of minority rule, widows managed their husbands' estates on behalf of a successor (Ch'ü 1961:104; Shiga 1978:120; Holmgren 1985:7,16); and widows maintained rights in heir and spouse selection (Ch'ü 1961:30-31, 104; Waltner 1981:142; Ebrey 1984a:234-37). Widows also demanded total obedience from the father's sons (Ch'ü 1961:120-2l; Ch'ü 1972:53). In its broader form, filial piety—obedience to parents, with the wife subordinate to the husband (see Mann's chapter in this volume)—underpinned the entire moral-political order from the highest levels of society down to the village.

Although members of the ruling family had to marry down in the native Chinese state, care was taken that alliances were contracted with families from the highest stratum of the elite. The intention was not so much to conform to any ideal of class endogamy but rather to control powerful interest groups. The usual pattern was for early supporters of the founder, often


61

military leaders, to be given preference in marriage relations until such time as they had ceased to be actively involved in the critical functions of government. There was thus a strong pull toward repetitive intermarriage with the same set of families. But the marriage circle always remained open, tending to evolve according to shifts in the ruling elite.[2]

Where members of the ruling family were concerned, senior officials of the outer court (chosen, in theory, according to merit) acted as guardians of the moral-political order (see Fang 1952:106-7; 1965:384; Fitzgerald 1968:27-28; Chung 1981:47, 62-63). This is not to say that strong-minded rulers and those who controlled the throne, including senior bureaucrats, did not try to manipulate custom and law when it suited their purpose.[3] Indeed, as a group, senior officials often openly agreed to bend or break some rules in order to square conditions with other, more important considerations. They would not usually object, for example, to an emperor's wish to promote his favorite concubine to the rank of empress if that position were vacant and if the concubine were the mother of the eldest son (see Chung 1981:47, 49). As we shall see, the practical need to override the established rule that a concubine should not be elevated to the status of wife derived from the particular form of succession that operated at the imperial level.

Rather than partible inheritance among all sons regardless of the mothers' status—the normal and preferred option among the scholar-elite and peasantry (Schurmann 1955-56:511-12; Shiga 1978:135, 141-43)—only one person could succeed to the throne. That person was the eldest son born of the empress (Tao 1978:173-75; Chang 1966:5-6).[4] If she produced no son, the eldest, regardless of his mother's position, was usually selected as heir, with the empress/wife acting as titular mother (also discussed by Thatcher in this volume). The heir (and his eldest son) resided in the palace beside his parents. All other sons were given fiefs at some distance from the locus of power. Although well provided for, they spent their lives in political obscurity. Direct access even to the wealth of the fief was denied, centralized bureaucratic control over its management being absolute. In sum, a distinction was drawn between male offspring on the basis of seniority and the status of the mother, with inheritance portions for younger sons being limited to a share of the tax revenue. Such was the case in the mature systems of all major Chinese regimes.[5]

Because younger sons of the emperor were without political, military, or fiscal authority, the only kinship bonds that could be effectively used by the throne for political purposes were its ties to wife-givers and wife-takers. The marriages of women—both the bestowal of the ruler's aunts (FZ), sisters, and daughters on families outside the palace and the entry of women into the imperial harem—therefore took on unparalleled political importance, with the ruler's maternal relatives becoming at once his chief means of support


62

and a most dangerous threat to his independence. The section below outlines the main features of the relations between the emperor, his mother, and his wife.

Whenever the throne was vacant or the emperor too young, ill, or feeble-minded to govern in his own right, the wife in the oldest surviving generation (empress, empress dowager, or grand empress dowager—hereafter referred to as the "widow" or "senior widow") acted as regent for state affairs (Chao 1937:155-58; Yang 1968:50-51; Bernard 1972:65-75). When the main line failed, the widow selected an heir from among her husband's collateral kin (de Crespigny 1975:5). She also had powers of spouse selection and dethronement. Even when she was little more than a child, with de facto power in the hands of senior members of the bureaucracy who were her natal relatives (as happened in the case of the fifteen-year-old empress dowager, née Huo, of Former Han [Tao 1978:179]), the legal power of dethronement still lay with her (Wallacker 1987). In all this, the empire was treated as family property, the chief difference being that the widow worked in concert, not with her husband's collateral kin, but with senior members of the bureaucracy who were either unrelated to the throne or were its wifely or maternal kin.

Whereas the role of the widow accorded with basic Chinese principles of family management and the all-important code of filial piety and was considerably strengthened by the political restrictions imposed on male agnates, filial piety and the idea of a female regent were at odds with the concept of sovereign power of the emperor (see Ch'ü 1972:59). The compromise was an uneasy one, for it involved voluntary withdrawal by the widow, keeping her powers of heir selection and dethronement in reserve for times of emergency. In practice, the widow usually withdrew from court in the formal way demanded by the bureaucracy but continued to maintain her hand in government affairs through (1) her psychological advantage as the emperor's mother or grandmother; (2) controlling the marriage process; and (3) placing her male kin in key civilian and military posts. These strategies were first put into place in imperial times by the empress dowager, née Lü (d. 180 B.C .), of the Former Han (Ward-Czynska 1978:2-6) and from there became the standard means by which ambitious mothers, wives, and favorite concubines tried to perpetuate their influence. In these cases, MBD/FMBSD alliances for heirs to the throne (figure 2.1) aimed to avoid a clash with incoming women, while the placement of relatives in strategic administrative posts ensured control over information reaching the throne.

In the native Chinese state it was thus common 'to find relatives of the senior widow controlling communication between the emperor and the outer court. No consort family managed, however, to maintain its political dominance for more than two or, at the most, three generations of rule. One difficulty lay in the legal restrictions imposed on intermarriage with close kin, and another in the role played by senior members of the bureaucuracy as


63

figure

Fig. 2.1.
Marriage with MBD/FMBSD in the Chinese state

guardians of the moral-political order, which led to their consequent interest and participation in the spouse-selection process (see Fitzgerald 1968:27-28; Chung 1981:62-63). Senior ministers jealously guarded their right to independent access to the throne and, through that, their right to join the imperial marriage circle. There were thus no customs or laws limiting the choice of wife to women from one particular family or group of families. This meant, however, that the system suffered from chronic tension between the throne, consort families, and the larger bureaucratic elite.

Another factor that prevented the development of a closed marriage circle lay in the custom whereby the wife could not control the marriage process until after the death of her husband.[6] Consequently, she often controlled only the marriage of a grandson and was thus constantly at odds with her son's wife chosen either by her husband or by his mother or grandmother. In this way, conflict between successive generations of imperial wives became a recurrent theme in the history of the native state. In the outer court, the conflict was represented by alliances between relatives and supporters of the ruler's grandmother and wife against the family of his mother.[7] From the emperor's point of view, his mother's family was useful in combatting either the combined influence of his grandmother and wife or that of the bureaucrat-


64

ic elite in general whenever it obstructed his purpose. Thus, when the emperor was in control, he often gave his mother's relatives the choice posts for high office.[8] In this way, the top echelons of the bureaucracy were rarely free from domination by consort kin, yet the position of any one family was highly unstable, with the death of an influential widow often heralding a violent shake-up of the administration.

Having lived long enough to reach the status of senior widow able to control the marriage of her grandson, a woman found that any alliance with her family arranged for the heir was marred by the incoming spouse, who came with a set of ready-made female relatives (namely, a mother and grandmother) whose loyalties often lay with their natal kin. Thus, the senior widow always faced competition from relatives of incoming wives (see figure 2.1), and the throne might ally itself with any one of these families against that of the widow. But perhaps the most serious problem faced by imperial wives and their relatives lay in biology: the empress was often not the biological mother of the incoming ruler. Infertility and high infant mortality certainly were factors,[9] but the emperor's deliberate sexual avoidance of the empress also played a role (see de Crespigny 1975:29). The dislike felt by many an emperor for his wife is easily explained: the woman was imposed on him when he was little more than a child. His favorite, then, was usually a concubine or palace attendant, and these women, rather than the wife, tended to conceive heirs to the throne.[10] The emperor's dislike of his empress intensified when she was a close relative of an overly dominant senior widow. She was then seen to be an enemy or spy and indeed often acted as such (ibid., 8; Chung 1981:62, 75-76).

Such marriage dynamics explain many incidents related in the historical accounts of the Chinese court. They also explain the great variety of adoption and informal support strategies used by unrelated females in the harem and palace service sector—for example, the protection an empress or influential wet nurse gave to a young attendant, slave, or orphaned child. Here, the older woman hoped the young protegée might become the prince's favorite and keep rivals away from the throne. Such strategies were most effective when they cut across social barriers in the outer society and status hierarchies within the palace. Only in this way could the older, more senior woman be fairly sure of maintaining her authority over the younger woman in the harem (see PCS 9:128; Fitzgerald 1968:18-20; Chung 1981:60; MS 113: 3514).

Like wives in the larger society, an empress could be divorced for barrenness (see Tai 1978), and many a ruler tried to use this law to rid himself of his wife following the death of the senior widow (see Ward-Czynska 1978:14-17; Chung 1981:28, 47; MS 113:3513). Yet from the middle of the Former Han when wives came mostly from powerful lineages with secure footholds in the upper echelons of the administration (see Ward-Czynska 1978), members of


65

the bureaucracy became increasingly adamant that the empress should not be cast aside simply to make way for a current favorite. In fact, T'ang and Sung law expressly forbad divorce on the ground of barrenness (Tai 1978:86-87). Against this, the bureaucracy had to weigh the cost of infighting between the biological concubine-mother and the titular mother (and regent) when both women survived into the next generation. Then, a clash of wills was inevitable. The Chinese solution to this problem was to prevent wherever possible the separation of the wife's political functions from her biological one of producing an heir to the throne. To this end, officials invariably agreed to elevate a favorite concubine who had produced the eldest son to the rank of empress if and when the current empress died or was divorced. The possibility of such promotions, however, encouraged rulers and favorite concubines, and sometimes mothers and maternal relatives, to engineer the death or disgrace of the empress, a problem also recorded for preimperial times (see Thatcher's chapter in this volume).

Given the frequency with which concubines' sons came to the throne (see n. 10), a ruler might well be surrounded by, not two, but up to four distinct sets of competing relatives centered around his biological and titular mothers (dowager empresses) and his biological and titular grandmothers (grand dowager empresses), some or all of which might be competing with the family of his wife (the empress). This competition, it should be noted, was important in preventing usurpation of the throne by consort families. Wang Mang (r. A.D . 9-23), whose case provides one of the few examples of successful usurpation, had to remove three other consort families from power before he could properly begin to engineer his coup d'état (Dubs 1955:44-49; Loewe 1974:286-306; Ward-Czynska 1978:41-47, 56-61). In contrast to Wang Mang, most imperial relatives confined themselves to the more realistic goal of domination. Even so, the lack of support from male agnates and the permanent tension among consort families, the throne, and members of the bureaucratic elite meant that fear of maternal kin was a major destabilizing factor in the history of the native state.

We have seen that an imperial wife held an unstable position in the early years of her career, when she relied in large part on the senior widow and members of the bureaucratic elite (including her own kin) for protection. With her husband's death, however, she might become head of the ruling house and on many occasions de facto ruler of the empire. Here, the widow not only assumed leadership of the ruling house but also (and quite logically) the de facto headship of her natal lineage (see Ch'ü 1972:58-59). Her influence was most widely felt when the emperor was her biological son or grandson and when he was young, weak-willed, or uninterested in government affairs. Thus, she invariably chose an infant or child rather than an adult when in a position to exercise her authority in choosing an heir (see HHS 10A:423). But the accession of a series of young and ineffectual rulers,


66

as occurred during the Later Hah (see Ch'ü 1972:215-16), did little for the morale of the administration because direct access to the throne was effectively blocked for all but the woman's family and supporters. For this reason, the death of an influential senior widow often heralded a violent fall in status for her family, sometimes bringing in its wake the death or disgrace of the empress and/or the wife of the heir-apparent.

In contrast to relatives of the emperor's mother and wife (wife-givers), the husbands and offspring of his sisters and daughters (sororal, or wife-taking, kin) were in a weak position when it came to succession politics. Sisters and sisters' sons were ineligible for the throne, and sororal kin were excluded from regency powers both by custom and by jealous wifely/maternal kin. In this way, however, the marriages of imperial sisters and daughters provided the throne with a way of establishing nonthreatening relations with influential members of the bureaucratic elite.[11]

As with incoming women, sororal ties were established by emphasizing customs and laws found in the wider society—property shares for daughters in the form of dowry (see Ch'ü 1972:273 n. 107, 283; Tai 1978:105-6; Ebrey 1981; Holmgren 1985) and educational and economic strategies centered on the mother (see Waltner 1981:144-52; Walton 1984:44-49). In addition, sororal ties benefited from the law of inheritance, that is, ranks and titles conferred on a woman without reference to her husband or son were to be treated as if granted to a man (TL 2:38; Johnson 1979:100-101). In the case of the princess, this condition was achieved by dispensing with the general law that made married women liable for punishments meted out to members of the husband's lineage (TCTC 76:2425). The princess's exemption from this law (see Ch'ü 1972:57; HTS 83:3647, 3650, 3653) meant that her status in no way depended on the position of her husband and his family. Rather, she retained her membership of the ruling line and was subject only to the throne (see Tang 1975:42; Wong 1979:136-37; DMB 1976.1:211). Because her status was conferred without reference to her husband, it could pass to her children. Thus, so long as they did not become wittingly involved in plots against the emperor, sororal cousins, nephews, and nieces were, like their mothers, exempt from severe punishment (see SKC 50:1198; 57:1340).

The material wealth a princess brought into marriage symbolized her condition. The lavish wedding gifts provided by the throne (see Chaffee's chapter in this volume) indicated the social and political superiority of her natal lineage over the husband and his family; the fief and its accompanying stipend (see Bielenstein 1967:21-22) symbolized that marriage had not altered her status. If the marriage lasted, most of the property eventually passed to the husband's family and out into the wider society through the woman's Offspring, the fief title going to her eldest son in accordance with the general law (see Dull 1978: 63 n. 188; Tang 1975:100; Shiga 1978:118). As befitting their elevated status as honorary members of the imperial line, the


67

woman's sons received imperial patronage in selection for high office. In this way, the sororal bond was transformed into an arm of the ruling line, reaching out into the wider community and establishing pockets of loyalty within other, potentially dangerous, lineages without the threat of domination or usurpation.[12]

Although the recipient lineage derived some comfort from the knowledge that at least one of its branches was insulated from political disaster, the throne benefited more from the arrangement because the princess could be counted on to put the imperial interest above that of her husband's family (see n. 12). For the woman's part, her exemption from severe punishment gave her a personal freedom denied to other members of the society, including her brothers. Unlike male agnates, who were perceived as a threat to the throne, the princess could remain in the capital at the center of power. Moreover, being female, she was not barred from the inner recesses of the palace as were the male officials of the outer court. Nor was she confined to the palace like an imperial mother or wife. In every respect, then, she was ideally placed to act as a power broker between the throne and families of the wider elite.

As a permanent member of the ruling line, the social status of the princess was higher than that of the imperial mother or wife. Indeed, her social position closely approximated that of the emperor himself. During the Southern Dynasties (A.D . 317-589), one woman used her exalted position to argue that, like her brother, the emperor, she too should have a harem. She was given thirty male "concubines" (Wong 1979:10). In short, although the princess never reached the political heights of an imperial mother or wife who acted as regent and de facto ruler of the state, and although her influence had no strong legal basis, her freedom of movement was considerable and her position solid. Because her status was not conditioned by ties beyond the throne, her influence depended on the accession of a strong ruler able to control his maternal relatives and to override any objections from the bureaucracy about her behavior. The tension between sisters and wives (princesses and empresses) at the imperial level was thus acute. Moreover, because all attention was directed toward a single male, competition among the princesses themselves was also intense—both among sisters and among different generations of female offspring (FFZ, FZ, and Z; see n. 15).

The princess's considerable status, which she passed to her children, meant that those children were eminently suitable as spouses for the next generation of imperial offspring. In fact, rulers often gave their children in marriage to sororal nephews and nieces. Although it was relatively easy, however, for a favorite sister to persuade her brother to give one of his many daughters in marriage to her son, her ultimate aim was to marry one of her daughters to the heir-apparent (FZD). Such a union would enable her to become de facto ruler of the state through her daughter, who would be in line


68

figure

Fig. 2.2.
Marriage with FZD/FMDD in the Chinese state

for the position of empress. Here, however, the princess faced fierce opposition from the ruler's grandmother, mother, and wife, as well as from other princesses with the same ambition. The senior widow, in conjunction with members of the outer court, controlled the marriage of the heir. So in practice a princess might achieve her ambition only (1) if she were the favorite sister of a strong-minded ruler whose mother and grandmother had passed away; (2) if she were the biological daughter of the senior widow; or (3) if an accident brought to the throne a younger half brother of the appointed heir—one who had previously married into her family (figure 2.2). Some women attempted to induce the latter condition by forming an alliance with an imperial concubine who had a son in order to bring about the disgrace and demotion of the appointed heir and his mother. But few women were able to bring such a complex strategy to fruition.[13] In practice, then, the empress in the native Chinese state was often a maternal cousin of the emperor (MBD or MBD/FMBSD), but she was rarely his paternal cousin (FZD).[14] In this way, sororal relatives (or wife-takers) tended to remain somewhat separate from wifely/maternal kin (or wife-givers), again helping to prevent the emergence of a truly aristocratic closed marriage circle. In short, the open-ended marriage system described in the chapter by Thatcher for the Spring and Autumn period continued on into late imperial times.

The political importance of the sororal bond for the throne meant that unmarried aunts (FZ), sisters, and daughters were always in short supply. Thus, those who were widowed (with or without children) usually remarried. If a recipient family fell from grace, the woman might well be summarily


69

divorced and given to another lineage, young sons following her into the new alliance. Because a favorite sister was also well placed to obtain a divorce on grounds of incompatibility and because marital discord might itself bring political catastrophe to the lineage, it was not unusual for an imperial princess to become the de facto head of the husband's family, controlling its finances, organizing its marriages, and determining its political strategy. For this reason, some families tried to avoid a sororal relationship with the throne (see Ch'ü 1972:295-96; Wong 1979:206 n. 66). The problem was not confined, however, to imperial relationships: any family interested in furthering its economic, political, or social condition through the upward marriage of a son chanced subordination to the wife and her kin (on this point see Chaffee's chapter).

Although this inversion of the normal husband-wife relationship brought complaints (see HHS 62:2052-53; Wong 1979:95-96, 99; and below), and although praise might be heaped on the princess who refused to remarry after widowhood or forced divorce (see Sui shu 80:1798), greater exception was taken to women who flaunted their superior status before the husband's parents, thus violating the code of filial piety. In such cases, senior officials pressured the throne into trying to get the princess to moderate her behavior. As we have seen, however, the issue of filial piety posed an even greater problem for the emperor's personal relationships. Divorce was kept within reasonable bounds by the knowledge that a crucial political alliance was at stake and by the idea that the severing of an established bond between a man and his wife for political gain was objectionable to senior members of the bureaucracy because it undercut family harmony, the foundation stone of the moral-political order, and because they themselves were the potential victims of policies embracing arbitrary divorce (see Chaffee's chapter in this volume). In the main, then, an imperial princess was not summarily divorced unless her husband suffered a drastic punishment like exile or execution. At the same time, princesses, unlike other women, were not expected to undergo any hardship or punishment that might accrue to the husband's lineage, and a man who abused his princess-wife (whatever the provocation) could be sentenced to death (see Ch'ü 1972:58).

In summary, we can say that the political impotence of the emperor's male agnates, who were greatly distrusted by both the throne and the bureaucracy, heightened the political significance of the marriages of women and the position of the emperor's mother, wife, aunt (FZ), sister, and daughter. The mother, or senior widow, and her relatives provided support both against the ambitions of male collateral kin and against the larger bureaucratic elite when either attempted to obstruct the will of the throne. For this reason (and because the power of maternal kin was balanced only by sororal bonds established through the marriages of female offspring), the political authority of the imperial wife was greatly feared. Because attention was


70

focused on a single male (the emperor or his heir), however, competition · between different generations of imperial wives and between them and the ruler's sisters and daughters, as well as among sisters themselves, was fierce. Such rivalries helped to prevent the development of a monopoly by any one family, greatly reducing the threat of usurpation by maternal kin. Yet the marriage circle tended to follow shifts within the political elite, so that competition also destabilized government. The following discussion focuses on the development of this system and how the founders of some regimes addressed the problem posed by the power of maternal kin.

Historical Development and Evolution

Perhaps the nearest a native Chinese regime came to instituting an exclusive system of marriage exchange with one particular family was at the beginning of the Former Han, when the empress dowager, née Lü (d. 180 B.C .) arranged a series of strategic marriages in order to perpetuate control of the government by members of her family (Ward-Czynska 1978:2-5). With the struggle to oust the Lüs after her death, however, potential heirs to the throne who were connected with her family were killed. Moreover, the next emperor was chosen for the lowly status and meager numbers of his maternal and wifely kin (Ward-Czynska 1978:1-11; Tao 1978:178; Kamada 1962:80). The next few reigns saw a relatively free system of marriage that regarded the selection of a spouse as a purely private or family matter. No definitive marriage group emerged because little formal connection existed between consort families and the established elite. In this period, then, wifely and maternal kin were even more vulnerable to changes in fortune than in later times, when they had an independent foothold in the bureaucracy.

Emperor Wu (r. 140-87 B.C .) changed this marriage pattern. Coming to power through a palace intrigue manipulated by his paternal aunt (FZ), Emperor Wu began his reign under two warring consort factions (Ch'ü 1972:169). His first wife was his father's sister's daughter, chosen for him by his grandmother, the grand empress dowager, née Tou (FZD/FMDD; figure 2.3). He degraded his wife after the death of his grandmother, and replaced her with a singing girl introduced by one of his sisters (Ward-Czynska 1978:12-17; Loewe 1974:51). Then, after having lost his first heir through political intrigue, and with a very young son to succeed him, he tried to put an end to consort power by forcing the mother of that son to commit suicide. He chose three ministers of the outer court to act as regents after his death (Ward-Czynska 1978:20-25; Loewe 1974:35-70). But this strategy failed because the appointed regents, all of whom were connected by marriage, simply selected a relative (a child of six) to be wife and empress for the young ruler. This arrangement initiated a twenty-year period (87-66 B.C .) of complete subordination for both the bureaucracy and the throne to consort families (see Loewe 1974:73-81; Wallacker 1987:58-59). In the short term, then, Emperor Wu's strategy produced a return to conditions seen at the


71

figure

Fig. 2.3.
Family ties of Emperor Wu of the Former Han
* Empress dowager Po and Empress Po were kinswomen.

beginning of the dynasty; that is, to domination of the government by a particular consort group. In the long term, the strategy instituted a system that drew wives from families of the political elite, with members of that elite deciding marriages in consultation with the senior widow (see Ch'ü 1972: 173-74, 210-29).

In Emperor Wu's time, the last vestiges of regional authority given to male paternal kin were stripped away (see Kamada 1962; Tao 1974). Some three centuries later, however, under the state of Wu (A.D. 222-80) in southeastern China, princes of the house were once again given regional military powers and made coregents and advisers to the throne (see Fang 1952; 1965). This condition continued on through Western Chin (A.D. 265-316) and the South-


72

ern dynasties (A.D. 317-589) into the early T'ang period (see Grafflin 1980:183-93; Tang 1975:50-54). For later Chinese the dramatic events of Western Chin (see Straughair 1973:2-5; Grafflin 1980:26-29, 94-95) reinforced two separate messages: first, that authority allotted to the ruler's male agnates would probably result in succession disputes that might well bring down the regime, and, second, that constant vigilance was needed against the ambitions of imperial wives, who—like the empress, née Chia, of Western Chin—might be tempted to depose the legitimate heir in favor of one of their own relatives (CS 31:965; CS 53:1459-62).

By comparing the history of Western Chin with that of other eras that gave male agnates a share of political power (see n. 5), we can see that influential male kin complicated the alliance patterns described above. An imperial wife could now appeal not only to her natal kin but also to individual princes of the house for support against other women or against the throne itself. Conversely, a princess was also able to support, or gain the support of, uncles and brothers whenever the throne appeared to be overly dominated by imperial wives. At such times, the political activities of female offspring were no longer masked by the machinations of the throne or maternal kin. As a consequence, the normal patterns of conflict between women not only spilled over into the outer court, disrupting the functions of government, but also set one prince against another, creating instability in the succession. Such disruptions were common in early and middle Former Han, Wu, and early T'ang and during the Western Chin when civil war erupted.

In the state of Wu, the roles played by princesses of the ruling house in succession problems (see Fang 1965) prefigure those of the early T'ang era (see Tang 1975). One can discern these same outlines in the history of early and middle Former Han (see Ward-Czynska 1978). In these periods, imperial princesses were not only divided among themselves and set in opposition to particular wives and heirs to the throne but also on occasion found themselves opposed to their own husbands. As members of the bureaucratic elite, the husbands of princesses sometimes sided with the heir or with another prince of the house to oppose female influence in general (that of mothers, wives, and sisters). Such alliances account in part for the high rate of divorce and widow-remarriage among imperial princesses in these periods. In early T'ang the underlying gender conflict between the all-male bureaucracy and females who provided the throne with its personal base of support was intensified by the presence of Empress Wu acting as de jure ruler of the state (A.D. 684—707).[15]

In sum, conditions in early T'ang represent one of several major realignments of the elite marriage system. The first of these shifts occurred during the Later Han when the throne, the bureaucracy, and even individual mothers and wives became subject to males of the consort family (see Young 1986 for details); the last was to occur during the Ming dynasty when the


73

throne, mothers and wives, and their male relatives became subject to the bureaucracy, a development we shall discuss below.

It is commonly thought that with the establishment of the examination system in the T'ang-Sung era, late imperial China experienced a social and political mobility that put an end to the early aristocratic system of government and produced a concomitant shift away from class endogamy toward a marriage system in which rank could be exchanged for material wealth, scholastic repute, and so forth (see Ebrey's chapter, this volume). The status of emperor is said to have changed from that of "first among equals" (many of whom provided spouses for the imperial house) to autocrat (Sung) and, finally, to tyrant (Ming). The despotic tradition of the Mongol-Yuan era (c. A.D. 1200-1360) is believed to have influenced the development of tyranny during the Ming dynasty. In a recent study of imperial marriage strategy in the mid T'ang, Chang Pang-wei (1986) linked the idea of a shift away from class endogamy to a demonstrated decrease in the proportion of imperial wives and concubines coming from the upper ranks of the elite. But other scholars have begun to question the accuracy of the underlying hypothesis: they suggest that depictions of pre-T'ang society as particularly static and of Sung society as highly mobile may be exaggerated. They also challenge the idea of a Mongol tradition of despotism arid the view of the late Ming ruler as tyrant.[16] The discussion below investigates some of these issues as they relate to imperial marriage under the Sung and Ming dynasties.

During Sung, certain founding families of the dynasty continued to provide spouses for, and to receive women from, the royal house long after their political fortunes had begun to wane.[17] This is one immediate explanation of Chang Pang-wei's data. By late Northern Sung these and other sororal kin were, furthermore, being specifically denied top-level posts in the central administration (SS 223:13579; SS 248:8777; HTCTC 153:4094; and Chaffee's chapter in this volume). In other words, royal spouses were no longer automatically chosen from the bureaucratic elite, and members of consort families were no longer given key administrative positions to the extent that they were able to enter and dominate the top ranks of the bureaucratic elite. The change had little to do with shifting attitudes toward marriage in the wider society. Rather, the initial impetus came from the throne and was an unintended side-effect of efforts to limit the power of the military. To this end, the first ruler of Sung came to an agreement with the founding generals of his regime that the latter would forgo real power in return for guaranteed social status through marriage ties with the royal house (Chung 1981:25). In fact, successful demilitarization of the political structure was a difficult and complex matter achieved through strategies that had nothing to do with marriage relations. Once demilitarization was under way, however, newly emerging bureaucratic groups saw the advantages of a policy that paired members of the ruling line with spouses from elite families on the decline.


74

The weakened relationship between political power at the top of the bureaucratic hierarchy and marriage relations with the throne also suited imperial wives. They could now dominate political affairs as dowagers and regents without hindrance from their male relatives or the emperor's sororal kin. For the consort families themselves, elevated social status coupled with political advantage at the lower levels of the hierarchy helped to sustain respectability at the local level (see Chung 1981:64-68, 79; Chaffee's chapter in this volume).

The growing disparity between the social and educational attributes of Sung, princesses and their spouses heightened the former's haughtiness toward their husbands and in-laws—a phenomenon that hardened attitudes about the husband's superiority over his wife and the wife's subordination to her husband's parents. This development was independent but supportive of trends in the larger society. The declining status of imperial marriage partners in general led to discussion of the qualities required of an empress: here "pedigree," meaning membership in the founding elite and/or respectable middle-ranking military background, as well as individual social skills—education, intelligence, and reputation for ethical behavior (Chung 1981:24-25)—became the chief selection criteria.

If action against the power of consort families was particularly gentle in the Sung, this was not so in the Ming, the first native regime to maintain a deliberate policy of choosing imperial spouses from families with no bureaucratic connections (Soullière 1988). The strategy was not entirely new, however. It had been tried (with little success) as early as the first century B.C. by Emperor Hsuan (d. 49 B.C. ) of the Former Han (see Ward-Czynska 1978:32-34, 40-41). But then the strategy had ignored the fundamental issue—the widow's role as final arbiter of the political process. The Ming addressed this issue by placing an additional ban on the delegation of imperial authority to harem women (Greiner 1979/80:6-7, 47; Soullière 1984:138; de Heer 1986:10). This too had been tried in earlier times—by the founder of Wei (A.D. 220-65), who had tried to dispense simultaneously with both the authority of the widow and support from close male agnates (TCTC 69:2206). Relying largely on sororal kin and a few select fraternal bonds to establish ties with the political elite of the former regime, the Wei throne had quickly fallen prey to usurpation by outsiders (see nn. 5, 8, and 12). The Ming dynasty did not suffer this fate, but a parallel nevertheless exists in the weakening position of the Ming throne vis-à-vis the bureaucracy in the absence of key matrilateral support.

Like the state of Wei, Ming governments found they still faced the problem of delegating authority during minority rule. Ironically, although no empress ever became regent (Soullière 1984:138), senior widows retained the authority to appoint a regent and to choose heirs and spouses just as they had in third-century Wei (see Fang 1965:165-66, 337, 352; de Heer 1986:25-27).


75

In practice, an imperial wife during the Ming dynasty played much the same role, albeit less prominently, as she had in the past.

Ming marriage strategy originated with the founder of the regime and reached maturity over the course of several reigns. Spouses were selected from low-ranking military families in the capital area on the basis of temperament and physical appearance (Soullière 1988:1, 20, 23-24, 30). Without a solid political base, families of the bureaucratic elite that supplied women for the imperial house could not supply more than one empress (ibid., 39). Consequently, this period witnessed a degree of upward and downward social mobility among imperial in-laws not seen in the native state since early Former Han. It would seem, then, that the phenomenon observed by Chang (1986) wherein imperial wives were increasingly drawn from the lower ranks of the elite and even from commoner families is best explained, not by changing attitudes in the wider society, but by the increasingly deliberate denial of power to consort families. The rationale and strategies underpinning this development during the Ming dynasty were firmly rooted in the Chinese tradition of pre-T'ang times.

Studies of Ming imperial marriage relations by Soullière (1984, 1987, 1988) support the current view that, far from being a despot, the Ming ruler had gradually been reduced to titular ruler and was made a virtual prisoner in his own palace. Without a powerful consort family as his ally, he was unable to assert his independence against the bureaucracy and sometimes sought to withdraw from the system entirely, forcing senior bureaucrats to turn to eunuchs and harem women for help in maintaining the link with the palace (Soullière 1984:132-34). In this period there was a swing away from educating imperial princesses in the virtues of wifely submission (as in the Sung) toward that of teaching their husbands and in-laws the art of being subordinate (see Soullière 1988:21). The development accorded with the new relationship between the bureaucratic elite and eunuch factions in the palace in cutting the emperor off from his traditional base of support. In short, the policy developed by the founder of the Ming to ensure the integrity of the throne against imperial wives and consort families was gradually appropriated by the bureaucratic elite so that all imperial women—mothers, sisters, and wives—now owed obedience, not to the husband or to male natal kin as in the past, but to the outer court.

In summary, power at the Chinese court oscillated between three officially sanctioned forces: the emperor, the senior widow, and members of the bureaucracy. Four other forces lay on the periphery (eunuchs, not dealt with here, and the emperor's paternal, sororal, and wifely/maternal kin). Any of these could be called into action by one of the major parties. Whether in Han times or Ming, however, the key to major shifts in the balance of power lay with close male relatives of the widow (wifely/maternal kin). When they were in a position to bridge the gap between the harem and the outer court by


76

occupying senior positions in the bureaucracy, power tended to swing away from the throne and unrelated members of the bureaucratic elite toward the widow and her family. Conversely, the widow was at her weakest whenever her natal kin had no established foothold within the bureaucratic elite. When this happened—as in the Wei (Three Kingdoms) and the Ming—power initially resided with the throne but tended to gravitate quickly toward the bureaucratic elite. Caught between the other two forces, the throne attempted to play off the widow's party against the bureaucratic elite, or to invoke the aid of one of the lesser peripheral bodies named above.

Accounts of the relationship between the emperor and these other parties were mostly composed, or at least approved, by men whose families had well-established relationships with sectors of the bureaucracy mainly outside the imperial marriage system. Thus, any choice of words in these accounts suggesting despotism on the part of the emperor or usurpation of power by imperial wives, relatives, or eunuchs should be seen as a signal of a significant shift in power away from the bureaucratic elite. Conversely, literature on the Sung indicates the stable and equitable balance of power between the major parties. A similar absence for mid- to late Ming, however, would reflect the complacency of a dominant bureaucracy. In other words, the mature Sung and Ming dynasties were seen to have largely avoided not only the "faults" of the Later Han, when the bureaucracy (as well as the throne and individual wives) had been subject to the consort clan, but also the "problems" of Wu, Western Chin, and early T'ang in dealing with the emperor's paternal kin as well as the various evils of late T'ang, when eunuchs had been the dominant policymakers.

We have seen how shifts in the balance of power during the Sung and Ming dynasties were in fact brought on by one of the constants of early Chinese history—namely, the acknowledgment by all parties that the position of the senior widow was such that the emperor and the bureaucratic elite could best (or perhaps only) assert their power by breaking the bond between political service and intermarriage with the throne. In this respect, the institution and the development of a public examination system (T'ang-Sung) possibly helped to weaken that bond. Yet the examination system was only a coincidental factor, for, as we have seen, conditions under the Ming were quite unlike, and in no way contingent upon, developments in either the T'ang or Sung dynasties. Moreover, and most important, each of those developments, as well as those that took place during the Ming, fell within parameters of change (both structural and ideological) already set in place by the end of the third century A.D. In short, despite major social changes in the wider society (see Ebrey and others in this volume), structure and strategy at court remained much the same in the native Chinese state from Han through to the end of Ming.


77

The Non-Han State

In the non-Han culture of the steppe, marriage may be characterized as (1) a transaction in which considerable wealth (or its substitute, labor) passed from the family of the groom to that of the bride (i.e., the "brideprice"); (2) a polygynous arrangement whereby all wives, or a group of senior wives, had equal status; (3) cross-generational alliance; (4) separate residence for married sons; and (5) an exogamous system in which intermarriage with the paternal line was permitted after a given number of generations (five, seven, or nine) (see Krader 1963). Women were well integrated into the husband's family, so much so that they sometimes received a personal share of the husband's patrimony apart from that given to male offspring. This in turn meant that wives rarely left the husband's family to remarry. Should a widow be unable to survive on her share of the patrimony, that share would be amalgamated with that of another male in the family through the levirate—marriage to a brother, uncle, nephew, or son (by another woman) of the late husband. Polygamy, separate residence for adult sons, and the absence of a ban on cross-generational marriage alliance facilitated the movement of widows from one unit of the family to another (see Holmgren 1986b).

Leaders were selected primarily on the basis of maturity and competence, thus obviating the need for regents—male or female (Holmgren 1981-83b; Fletcher 1986; Holmgren 1986c, 1987). This meant that consort families participated in government only as heads of tribal subunits within the confederation, not as wifely, sororal, or maternal kin. Because marriage could not be used by one group to undermine the authority of another, it was able to develop as a diplomatic device, usually taking the form of a simultaneous exchange of women conducted across a range of leaderships. The condition contrasts with that of the Chinese state, which was hampered in foreign marriage diplomacy by its emphasis on lineal succession, monogamy, and the role of the wife and her relatives in supporting the throne during minority rule (Holmgren n.d.).

For China specialists, the absence of steppe customs in states of non-Han origin, or the presence of forms approximating those found in the native Chinese regime, is often seen as evidence of sinification. But similarities can be misleading. One cannot assume that they arise for the same reasons. For example, the Ch'i-tan (Khitan) abandoned the exchange of women with foreign states during the Liao period (A.D. 916-1122) because one particular group of outsiders had been given an exclusive permanent lien on marriage relations with the ruling house. In fact, the Chinese model was never completely adopted by any conquest regime. Rather, individual elements of the model were selected, modified, and integrated with the steppe tradition. In each case, the mix provided a well-integrated, workable system of control


78

designed to meet specific political needs. At the same time, each approach was unique; that is, the amalgam of Chinese and steppe traditions was never exactly the same.

The variety and political ingenuity of systems developed by non-Hah states are demonstrated below. Here it remains to point out some common characteristics. First, nearly all non-Han states actively discouraged or severely circumscribed marriage ties between the throne and the Chinese. Second, the circle of imperial marriage partners tended to remain relatively stable, and consequently the various sets of in-laws overlapped to a much greater extent than in the native Chinese regime; that is, the same groups continued to supply both wives and husbands for imperial offspring almost indefinitely. Third, in non-Han states there was a more carefully regulated, and thus much greater, correlation between political privilege and social status as seen through marriage relations with the royal house than in the Chinese state (on these points, see also Rawski's chapter in this volume). Even Northern Wei, the one great exception to these generalizations, moved toward this type of system in its later years.

All these characteristics grew out of the need to protect the non-Han minority's privileged place in government against encroachment by the Chinese. Finally, examination of the histories of these northern conquerors in predynastic and dynastic times reveals a link between the abrupt appearance of new forms and attitudes to marriage and a shift in power-sharing among males of the ruling lineage. The link is highlighted most forcefully in T'o-pa history, which saw two quite distinct shifts in attitudes to marriage and inheritance—the first occurring during the foundation era, the other at midpoint in the history of the imperial state. A similar, equally dramatic shift can also be observed in early Ch'i-tan and Mongol history (see Holmgren 1987). The sections below outline the main features of the marriage systems that developed in tandem with this new approach to power-sharing among male kin. As we shall see, the systems so devised had little in common with each other or with the model established by the native Chinese state.[18]

The T'o-pa Wei

Northern Wei (A.D. 399-534) developed a marriage system that emphasized the common interest between the throne and collateral branches of the ruling house in controlling the ambitions of outsiders, both Chinese and non-Han. That is, Wei marriage strategy protected the privileged place of paternal kin in selection for office by denying other interest groups access to power through marriage ties with the throne. Thus, in spirit and form Northern Wei policy resembles that of the Ming: imperial wives and concubines came from outside the ranks of the bureaucratic and military elite; there was active discrimination against the ruler's wifely and maternal kin in selection for high office; and there were few cross-ties between sororal and wifely kin; that


79

is, daughters of princesses (FZD) and maternal cousins (MBD) were not taken into the imperial harem.

Wei strategy went much further, however, in that the T'o-pa attempted to separate the wife's biological function of producing an heir from her political role. First, mothers of eldest sons were never appointed to the rank of empress in their lifetimes and might well be made to commit suicide after the son was named as heir to the throne. Second, empresses were appointed only on an irregular basis and were invariably childless. They did not act as titular or foster mothers to eldest sons, and they all came from the ruling families of recently conquered states and thus had few if any relatives of influence in the outer court. They were thus purely symbolic figures representing the integration of their peoples into the T'o-pa empire. In short, the T'o-pa adopted the Chinese principle of primogeniture but rejected the idea of succession by a son of the empress. They thus dispensed with the most critical aspect of the Chinese system—the role of the senior widow as head of the ruling house and de facto head of state in times of political crisis. Under the T'o-pa such crises were to be addressed by senior officials of the outer court who were either unrelated to the throne or were princes of the blood or select sororal kin. In this system, imperial princesses were given in marriage either to leaders of refugee groups arriving in Wei from other states, or to members of a select line of a non-Han lineage (the Mu family). In the former case, the aim was to neutralize a potentially hostile group that had settled in the realm. In the latter instance, repeated bestowal of daughters upon sororal nephews (ZS) created a group of loyal kin who, being T'o-pa in all but name, could be chosen for office in the same way as princes of the blood, thus supplementing the latter's meager numbers. Care was taken, however, that these sororal bonds were never translated into wifely/maternal relationships.

Measures taken to control the ambitions of agnates centered not on supervising their marriages, but on bestowing equal rights in selection for office. Political rank and social standing within the ruling lineage therefore depended on loyalty and service to the throne as perceived by the emperor of the day. Thus, for princes of the house (the most privileged group in the empire), marriage was apolitical. And because brothers, nephews, and younger sons were free to choose wives without reference to the throne, many branches of the house intermarried with commoner, even slave, families—wives being chosen for reasons of love or physical beauty. It seems, then, that for the T'o-pa, the wife's social standing was of little consequence.

In summary, the early Wei ruler was not primus inter pares but a true autocrat who derived his chief support from, but nevertheless controlled in an absolute way, all members of the imperial lineage as well as senior bureaucrats of the outer court. In the early Wei system (400-490s) all paternal kin, males and females, were far more trusted than wives. Although the trust placed in sisters was in some cases extended to their husbands and sons,


80

sisters' daughters did not marry back into the imperial line to become wives and mothers of emperors. Nor were the female offspring of distant male agnates permitted to marry back into the ruling line, as might have happened in the steppe tradition.

In the 480s the throne began to use the marriages of female offspring to gain access to the social network of the Chinese elite. The change in policy was geared to the better integration of wealthy provincial Chinese into state-controlled political and economic structures. In this way, the policy of marriage avoidance with the bureaucratic elite began to break down. Other strategies remained in place, however, in particular those relating to the political power of mothers and wives. A decade later, the narrow aim of protecting the government positions of paternal kin was widened to encompass all non-Han elites. To this end, the system of selection to office was overhauled so that political rank now depended on social status, with the latter being defined (for the non-Han) by ancestral service or degree of blood/ marriage relation to the throne. The 490s thus saw a revival of the predynastic tradition whereby all lines of the ruling family were ranked according to seniority (birth). This revival was accompanied by a shift in attitude toward marriage for male offspring. That is, a controlled, elitist marriage strategy was developed during the 490s in an effort to establish a recognizable and "respectable" circle of families from which the ruling line and close paternal kin (males and females) could draw their spouses. From there, Wei moved rapidly toward the system seen under conquest regimes, namely, marriage exchange within a closed circle of mestizo and non-Han elites who dominated key administrative posts.

Such changes in the marriage system created instability in the top echelons of the bureaucracy as male agnates clashed with the throne over the issue of political privilege for relatives of the emperor's mother and wife. In addition, distant branches of the emperor's family suffered a decline in political status as they struggled to protect their place in government against incursions from the emperor's more privileged uncles and brothers and other non-Han elites who now had better access to power through wifely and maternal ties with the throne. In the search for ways to maintain their status, distant male kin turned to marriage alliance with the families of eunuchs and palace attendants. Here, long-term social security associated with membership of the imperial house was exchanged for informal, high-level (but often short-lived) political influence. Such cross-status alliances were no longer tolerated, however, for they were held to be subversive to the new political order.

The Ch'i-tan Liao

Whereas early Wei marriage strategy focused on protecting the throne and paternal kin from the ambitions of powerful outside interest groups, Liao (A.D. 916-1122) marriages were designed to minimize the dangers posed by


81

the emperor's male agnates. The system grew out of the support given to the founder of the regime by his wife and her family against other tribal leaders and, more important, against the founder's uncles and brothers, who refused to relinquish their traditional leadership rights. In this system, princes of the blood who were only distantly or remotely related to the throne were more trusted than close male agnates. Accordingly, the latter were given mainly honorary titles and nonfunctional posts associated with the shell of the old political order. As reward for their support in helping to institute the new monarchical and centralized system of government, the family of the first empress (an outsider in relation to the old power structure) was given exclusive rights to marriage relations with the throne and a hereditary lien on key posts in the newly developing system of administration.

In the mature Liao marriage system, all branches of the imperial house (the Yeh-lü) as well as those of the consort clan (the Hsiao) were ranked according to degree of kinship with the founding emperor and empress. The highest-ranking branches of the ruling family (the emperor and his close relatives) married into those of the consort clan and vice-versa. In this way, the ruler was supported not only by his mother and her uncles and brothers (who doubled as senior officials of the outer court), as in the Chinese system, but also by his mother's female kin—her sisters and nieces—who doubled as consorts for his uncles (FB), brothers, and nephews (BS). Here, cross-generational alliance flourished, with members of the consort clan marrying down into younger generations of the imperial house, all of which increased the likelihood that the empress's sisters and nieces would be able to control their husbands and thus help to protect the ruling line from the threat of armed revolt or usurpation by close paternal kin (figure 2.4).

The Liao system, then, was almost a parody of that of the Chinese. Ranking within the harem was determined by the political status of the woman's male kin, and the status of her male kin was determined by social rank defined according to blood ties with the founding empress and current ruler. The correlation of social status, selection for office, and provision of spouses for the royal house was thus much higher than ever intended or seen under any Chinese regime. This is not to say that there was no political and social mobility. Indeed, the middle Liao period saw considerable upward mobility as the throne attempted to weaken the power of relatives of the first empress by broadening the base of the consort clan: here, the new rules of surname exogamy, repetitive marriage-exchange, and hereditary rights to office were circumvented by the simple device of surname adoption; that is, by using the steppe practice of fictive kinship to integrate outsiders into the political system. The same device was later taken up by the consort clan as a means of incorporating its followers into the system. It was only after the system was revamped in the latter part of the regime (1020s) that genuine blood ties with the founding unit were stressed.

Although most Liao rulers married maternal cousins (MBD), distinctions


82

figure

Fig. 2.4.
Cross-generational marriage: Liao

such as MBD and FZD, relevant to the Chinese model, are less applicable because the system of exchange meant that a wife who was MBD might also be FZD. Cross-generational alliances complicated the situation. The eighth ruler, for example, married a woman who was his mother's paternal cousin (MFBD) and his father's maternal cousin (FMBD) (figure 2.5). Although Liao rulers could marry their maternal aunts (MZ) as well as daughters of the mother's or grandmother's brother (MBD or FMBD), they could not,


83

figure

Fig. 2.5.
Cross-generational marriage with MFBD/FMBD in late Liao

despite the high status of maternal aunts and cousins, take the female offspring of such women into the imperial harem (MZD). Liao practice here differed from China's because such offspring always carried the surname of the imperial house (Yeh-lü). This explains why power held by the empress's aunts and sisters did not pass to their offspring (although it did reappear in the following generation through the female line). For males of the consort clan, political status initially passed to both male and female offspring but from there was transmitted only through the male line. In short, all members of the consort clan, whatever their gender, tended to have more power than their spouses, including the emperor himself. Because the status of the empress dowager extended to her close relatives regardless of gender, the normal gender inequality between husband and wife was reversed, not for the emperor's sisters as in the Chinese model, but for those of the empress and empress dowager. The military authority assumed by these women in times of crisis (see Wittfogel and Feng 1949:200, 557) was a symptom of this condition.

In theory, the Liao system of marriage exchange should ultimately have


84

incorporated the consort clan into the imperial house to such an extent that all divergent interests between it, the throne, and paternal kin would disappear. The system favored the consort clan, however, more than it did the throne. Even in early Liao, the emperor was in danger of being overshadowed by members of the consort clan. Action taken to redress this situation was short lived, ending in the fourth reign with the emperor's personal withdrawal from government in a manner similar to that seen in the late Ming. In the latter part of Liao, however, the authority of the throne was protected to some extent by factionalism within the consort clan as wives of one generation battled with those of the next, and as barren empresses struggled to hold their place in the system against fertile concubines. In effect, the various branches of the consort clan began to behave in the same manner as competing generations of wifely and maternal kin in the native Chinese state.

The Mongol Yuan

In predynastic times the Mongol leadership (early 1200s) developed a marriage system that achieved a near-perfect balance among all the parties discussed above. It continued on into the Yuan era (A.D. 1260-1368) with very little change other than a gradual drift in administrative, fiscal, and military power away from the periphery toward the center. This shift ultimately left secondary branches of the imperial house unable to defend the integrity of the throne against bureaucratic forces.

Distinctions were horizontal in the Mongol system rather than vertical. Paternal relatives and the leaders of subordinate tribes and allied states were invested with identical powers that, although located away from the center, were basically imitative of those held by the supreme ruler in the central domain. In this system, close paternal kin tended to be more trusted than remotely related male agnates. Accordingly, they were given a significant amount of autonomy on the outermost rim of the empire. Their role as regional overlords and the local autonomy granted to other tribal leaders together formed the linchpin of government. Power, then, was invested as much on the periphery of the realm as at the center.

Participation by princes and allied leaders in the selection of the supreme ruler and strict supervision of marriage and succession procedures within the various kingdoms and fiefs were some of the means the center used to control the strong centripetal forces within the realm. By early Yuan times, inheritance of territories held by collateral branches of the house was regulated so as to emphasize service to the center and to prevent control of the fief from falling into the hands of outsiders. Older sons were expected to earn their own kingdoms, and the fief went, not to the youngest son of the wife in the traditional manner (ultimogeniture), but to the youngest adult son who had no fief of his own at the time of his father's death or to a collateral male relative who held the territory in trust until the youngest son came of age. In


85

this way, families that married into the ruling lineage were unable to gain control of the various princely domains. Marriage alliances were also carefully scrutinized by the center to prevent collusion between princes of the house and allied tribal leaders also on the periphery.

The local autonomy granted to conquered and allied leaders was contingent upon their acceptance of a sister or daughter of the Mongol ruler in marriage. This, combined with an enforced system of monogamy, lineal succession (ultimogeniture), and female regencies within the allied state, guaranteed effective control over the subject tribesmen by the central domain. In the final analysis, however, control rested on the demonstrated military superiority of members of the ruling house. Herein lay one of the chief weaknesses of the system: fragmentation could be prevented only by continuous conquest and expansion or by instituting an overarching bureaucratic structure controlled by the center. The latter development in the Yuan era (1270s) led to the emasculation of the male agnates' traditional powers and domination of the throne by senior officials of the outer court who were unrelated to the throne.

Traditional Mongol practice emphasized polygamy and the full integration of wives into the husband's family, so the position of the ruler's married sisters and daughters as agents for the natal line was an anomaly. Thus, in contrast to brideprice systems operating at other levels of Mongol society, the imperial princess was furnished with a lavish dowry symbolic of her continuing membership of the ruling house. At the same time, remnants of the traditional mentality wherein the husband regarded his wife (or wives) as an integral, permanent part of the family worked to the advantage of the ruling house in that the allied leadership did not see the woman's participation in the affairs of the kingdom as a gross imposition. The continued existence of traditional ideology is also seen in the center's use of the levirate: sisters and daughters who failed to produce offspring able to inherit the kingdom simply married the incoming heir—one of the late husband's uncles, brothers, nephews, or sons by another woman. In this way, the center managed to avoid problems of control arising from infertility, high infant mortality, and sexual avoidance.

In theory, pacts with allied leaders were between equals. Each allied group therefore had the right to exchange women with the ruling house in the traditional manner. The pacts were structured, however, to benefit the central domain rather than the allied kingdom. On the one hand, real sisters and daughters of Mongol rulers were sent out to become wives and mothers of the rulers of allied states, but on the other, women selected as spouses for the ruling house usually came from relatively powerless lines of the subject leadership—branches that in many cases had only a remote blood connection with the real leaders of the kingdom. This was particularly so where the Onggirat tribe was concerned, for it had a hereditary lien on the provision of


86

the senior wife who produced heirs for the supreme office. Thus, at the center, MBD alliances were as rare as those of FZD, and allied tribal leaders (sororal kin) had no chance of becoming wifely/maternal relatives of the emperor and were thus effectively barred from excessive interference in the affairs of the ruling house. All this helped to maintain an equitable balance of power between sororal and paternal kin stationed on the periphery of the realm.

Because the different sets of imperial relatives were confined to administrative duties associated with specific territories located beyond the center, the Mongol ruler, along with his mother and wife, worked in isolation with a group of advisers of non-Han, but largely non-Mongol, origin who were set quite apart from the marriage circle. In effect, then, the ruler's wife was cut off from her natal family both by physical distance and by sororal kin who controlled communication between the center and forces within the allied kingdom. As we have seen, identification of the empress with the interests of the throne and the bureaucracy free of reference to the aspirations of her natal kin had been a long-held dream of many Chinese. It was achieved by the Mongols primarily through the decentralized system of control, but the condition also accorded with traditional ideology that saw the wife as an integral part of the husband's family. In sum, the empress in the Mongol-Yuan dynasty was seen as an individual to be entrusted with power and authority in the same manner as an imperial sister or brother.

The alienation of brothers and sisters was prevented by their participation in the election of the supreme ruler. As in the Liao, all adult sons of the wife were potential heirs to the throne, with the final decision being made after the death of the ruler. The successor was chosen at an assembly of relatives who were major fief holders—princes of the house, the late ruler's paternal aunts (FZ), sisters, and daughters, their husbands and/or sons, and the late ruler's mother and wife. In the interim, either the youngest adult son by the wife, or the wife herself, acted as regent. Because only competent adults were eligible for the position of leader and adult males could assume regency powers, the opportunity for mothers and wives to assume the full powers of state fell well short of that provided by the Chinese system. As we have seen, in the Chinese state, male agnates were usually barred from holding regency powers, and the senior widow was able to govern in the name of an infant or child, retaining the power of dethronement. Neither that power nor heir selection was the sole prerogative of the Mongol wife; all such matters were decided through the family assembly.

This, then, was the system that prevailed in the early years of the Yuan dynasty. Expansion of the bureaucratic sector at the provincial and central levels in the dynastic era saw a gradual shift, however, in the balance of power away from the emperor at the center and the various kingdoms and fiefs on the periphery toward bureaucratic forces beyond the marriage circle.


87

In this shift, the power of the wife (the empress) moved away from her traditional place in the extended family of fief holders toward Chinese-style relations with members of the outer court. But, unlike conditions in most native regimes, her working relationship with senior officials was not supported by the presence of natal kin, and thus her position was far less secure than in the native state. As we have seen, such conditions had existed in the early state of Wei (A.D. 220-65), and a similar situation was to occur under the subsequent Ming regime, although in neither case did the system arise from influences or borrowings from the non-Han tradition.

Conclusion

We have seen that no non-Han regime was purely imitative of the native Chinese state. Rather, imperial marriage policy under conquest dynasties consisted of a judicious mix of elements taken from both the steppe and the Chinese tradition. In each case that mix provided the leadership with an integrated system of control geared to specific political demands. One demand common to all regimes was that the marriage system protect the privileged place in government of members of the non-Han community against encroachment by the Chinese. To this end each state focused on excluding or limiting in some way intermarriage with the Chinese and on emphasizing a direct correlation between political privilege and social status, with the latter being defined in part by consanguineous and marriage ties with the ruling house.

Despite the common focus on excluding or limiting ties with the Chinese, each dynasty developed a unique marriage system. The variety seen across different regimes stemmed in part from the different approach to traditional non-Han competitors, in particular the attitude toward the emperor's male agnates: early Northern Wei practice saw imperial marriage as a means of controlling outside groups for the benefit of all branches of the imperial house; the Yuan focused on protecting the throne and close collateral kin; and the Liao used marriage to control male agnates. The correlation between forms and attitudes to marriage and the approach to power sharing among males of the lineage in these states confirms the significance of a similar phenomenon noticed in the Chinese case. There, we saw how imperial marriage practice was based on customs and laws found in the larger society, with differences at the imperial level being determined in large part by the difference between succession and the mode of inheriting family property. It would seem, then, that whether in the non-Han or native Chinese regime, forms and attitudes to imperial marriage were strongly influenced by the relationship between the emperor and his uncles (FB), brothers, sons, and nephews (BS). That influence was felt not only in the degree of power sharing between the throne and agnatic kin but also in the physical proximity of


88

those relatives to the throne, the latter being responsible for some of the differences seen in the strategies devised by Northern Wei, where agnates rotated between the center and the periphery, and in the Mongol system, where they were permanently stationed on the frontier.

Under the mature Chinese state the ruling line stood alone, isolated both physically and psychologically from its collateral branches. Consequently, regency powers were invested in outsiders—namely, the late emperor's widow, who acted as head of the imperial lineage and on occasion de facto ruler of the empire. When her natal relatives were members of the bureaucratic elite stationed in the capital, her power was extended, indeed often delegated, to them. In this way, maternal kin became the chief means of support for the throne against paternal uncles, brothers, cousins, and nephews and against the larger bureaucratic elite. Because of this, however, maternal relatives were also a most dangerous threat to the ruler's independence. Because the power of the widow and her family was balanced only by the presence of the wider bureaucratic elite and a set of sororal bonds created through the strategic marriages of female offspring, fear of the consort clan was a perennial destabilizing factor, with the history of the native state becoming one of shifts in the balance of power among the throne, the bureaucracy, and imperial wives and their families. Such shifts took place within as much as across individual dynasties. Within this scenario, the political activities of the imperial princess were often obscured, her influence becoming fully evident in the historical narrative only when male agnates were able to provide a viable alternative to a weak throne dominated by mothers, wives, and maternal kin. In other periods, the power of the princess was manifest mainly in the record of social problems arising from her superior social position vis-à-vis her husband and his family.

In late imperial times, the Sung, Yuan, and Ming dynasties all saw a shift in the balance of power toward members of the bureaucratic elite unrelated to the throne. The Ming condition was not contingent, however, on developments in either the Sung or the Yuan dynasties. Indeed, in each dynasty, marriage systems arose from unique internal developments, with developments in the Ming occurring well within the parameters of change established for the native state in early times. In short, when the processes of change are viewed from the Hah dynasty through to the end of Ming, the T'ang-Sung transition era loses much of its apparent significance.

Both the Sung and the Ming regimes continued to be concerned about limiting the political influence of the imperial wife, and each developed a unique approach to traditional concerns about the status of the imperial princess vis-à-vis her husband. Conditions in the Sung dynasty permitted a more concerted effort toward complying with the status quo seen in the larger society; while Ming society endorsed earlier imperial practice, stressing the education of the husband to cope with his subordinate position. This latter


89

approach grew out of the Ming's general emphasis on the subordination of consort families to the bureaucratic elite.

In sum, imperial marriage in the Chinese state was based on customs and laws found in the wider society, deviations and anomalies being explained in large part by the form of succession that prevailed at the imperial level. Once established, the system endured in basic form throughout the imperial era, from Han times through to the end of Ming, with very little reference to changing attitudes and practices in the larger society or to new modes of operation introduced by conquest regimes. Neither the history of early T'ang (when the historical narrative takes great account of the political activities of mothers, wives, and female offspring) nor that of early Ming (which saw a concerted effort to restrict the power of the imperial wife) deviates from the model established for the native state in pre-T'ang times.

If we were to take that model as a standard reference point in any comparative study of marriage relations, we could say that the Northern Wei and Liao dynasties represent two extremes in the spectrum of Chinese attitudes toward male agnates and maternal kin. As we have seen, Northern Wei history was dominated by excessive fear of outsiders working through the maternal bond. The practices of that era were therefore hedged around with numerous devices for keeping mothers and wives and their families from power. In contrast, the Liao system was characterized by fear of male agnates and thus placed an exaggerated trust in mothers and wives and their natal relatives. Such was that trust, the Liao state dispensed almost entirely with the checks and balances seen in the Chinese state: members of the consort clan were permitted to dominate the bureaucracy through an exclusive permanent lien on key offices; and the function of marriage for an imperial princess was solely biological—that of reproducing the consort clan. Here, then, as distinct from all other regimes, the imperial princess was subject to the authority of her husband. Liao was also the only dynasty to extend the status and power of the wife to all her relatives, both male and female. In this system, then, sisters of the mother were more trusted and given greater powers than imperial princes and princesses.

Both the Wei and Liao dynasties structured their marriage systems on the centralized bureaucratic state. Thus, those systems can be easily compared with each other and with that prevailing under the native regime. In contrast, imperial marriage under the Mongols evolved to fit a decentralized feudal mode of administration in which female offspring played a critical role in preserving the authority and independence of male agnates stationed on the periphery of the realm. In part because of decentralized control, the Yuan was one of the few regimes successful in breaking the link between authority delegated to the senior widow and the status and power of her family. In the Yuan, the position of the imperial wife was never dependent upon that of her family. Rather, she was entrusted with power in the same


90

way as a sister or brother. Moreover, her authority did not challenge, and was not challenged by, the sister or brother. All three were integral, permanent members of the ruling house and thus social equals. Additionally, the sister and wife both had regency powers—the one on the periphery, the other at the center—and, like a brother, both participated in choosing the supreme ruler. This was not the case in the native Chinese regime, where the social status of the sister was higher than that of the wife and where her political influence was more solidly based, but where she was denied the chance to act as de facto ruler of the empire with authority in heir selection and dethronement.

In discussing the status of women among the ruling elite, it is therefore necessary to distinguish between different categories of females in the same generation (sisters and wives, wives and concubines, etc.). It is also necessary to distinguish between the attitude toward a political role for those different categories of women and the attitude toward their relatives and consort families in general. As we have seen, at least four regimes, two of Chinese origin and two of non-Han background (Northern Wei, Sung, Yuan, and Ming), managed to prevent domination of the throne by the emperor's maternal relatives. Only two states (Northern Wei and Ming), however, set out to achieve this by relieving the imperial wife of power: in Sung, the declining influence of maternal kin was a by-product of other concerns; while during the Yuan the authority of the wife remained intact even though her close kin were excluded from power.

Although both the Northern Wei and Ming dynasties, as well as the Yuan, succeeded in diminishing the influence of maternal kin, no regime was able to stop individual mothers and wives from amassing power. Even the Northern Wei, despite its brutal approach to this problem, was dominated on two separate occasions by female regents. And as we have seen, the Ming regime, like other Chinese dynasties before it, faced chronic problems of delegated authority during times of emergency and minority rule. Thus the wife continued to play much the same role as she had in Han, T'ang, and Sung times, albeit at a less prominent level. Ironically, the Liao regime, which gave greatest political privilege to maternal kin, saw only three influential dowagers—considerably fewer than under many Chinese regimes. In fact, neither Liao nor any other steppe or China-based non-Han regime offered the imperial wife greater legal authority and power than did the native Chinese state.

References

Primary Sources

CS Chin shuinline image, by Fang Hsuan-ling inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1974.

HHS Hou Han shuinline image , by Fan Yeh inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1973.


93

HS Han shuinline image, by Pan Ku inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1975.

HTCTC Hsu tzu-chih t'ung-chieninline image, by Pi Yuan inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1979.

HTS Hsin T'ang shuinline image, by Ou-yang Hsiu inline image and Sung Ch'i inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1975.

ML Ming-lü chi-chieh fu-liinline image. 1610; Taipei: Ch'eng-wen, 1970 facsimile of 1898 reprint.

MS Ming-shihinline image, by Chang T'ing-yü inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1984.

PCS Pei Ch'i shuinline image, by Li Te-lin inline image and Li Po-yao inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1972.

SHT Sung hsing t'unginline image, by Tou I inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1984.

SKC San-kuo chihinline image, by Ch'en Shou inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1975.

SS Sung shihinline image, ed. T'o T'o inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1977.

Sui shuinline image, by Wei Cheng inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1973.

TCTC Tzu-chih t'ung-chieninline image, by Ssu-ma Kuang inline image. Hong Kong: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1971.

TML T'ang Ming lü ho-pieninline image, ed. Hsueh Yun-sheng inline image. Kuo-hsueh chi-pen ts'ung-shu ed.

TL T'ang-lü shu-iinline image by Ch'ang-sun Wu-chi inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1983.

Secondary Works

Bernard, Elmar Maria. 1972. "Die Yuan-Hou und die Gesellschaftliche und Politische Stellung der Kaiserinnen gegen Ende der Ch'ien-Han-Periode" (Empress Yuan and the social and political position of empresses toward the end of Former Han). Ph.D. diss., Georg-August Universität zu Göttingen.

Bielenstein, Hans. 1967. "The Restoration of the Han Dynasty III." Bulletin of the Museum of Far Eastern Antiquities 39.2:5-198.

Chan, David B. 1976. The Usurpation of the Prince of Yen, 1398-1402 . San Francisco: Chinese Materials Center.

Chang, Curtis Chung. 1966. "Inheritance Problems in the First Two Reigns of the Sung Dynasty." M.A. thesis, University of Chicago.

Chang Pang-wei inline image. 1986. "Shih-lun Sung-tai 'hun-yin pu wen fa-yueh'" inline image (Examination of the Sung words "not considering family rank in marriage"). Sung Liao Chin Yuan shih , no. 2:21-36.

Chao Feng-chieh inline image. 1937. Chung-kuo fu-nü tsai fa-lü shang chih ti-weiinline image (Legal position of Chinese women). Shanghai: Commercial Press.

Chiba Hiroshi inline image. 1974. "Sodai no kohi; Taiso, Taiso, Shinso, Jinso shicho" inline image (The imperial consorts of Emperors T'ai-tsu, T'ai-tsung, Chen-tsung, and Jen-tsung of Northern Sung). In Sodaishi ronso (Collection of essays on Sung history), special anniversary volume presented to Sadao Aoyama. Tokyo: Seishin shobo.

Ch'ü T'ung-tsu. 1961. Law and Society in Traditional China . Paris: Mouton.


94

———. 1972. Han Social Structure . Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Chung, Priscilla Ching. 1981. Palace Women in the Northern Sung, 960-1126 . Leiden: E.J. Brill.

de Heer, P. H. 1986. The Care-Taker Emperor: Aspects of the Imperial Institution in Fifteenth-Century, China as Reflected in the Political History of the Reign of Chu Ch'i-yu . Leiden: E.J. Brill.

de Crespigny, R. R. C. 1975. "The Harem of Emperor Huan: A Study of Court Politics in Later Han." Papers on Far Eastern History 12:1-42.

DMB (Dictionary of Ming Biography, 1368-1664 ). 1976. Ed. L. C. Goodrich and Fang Chao-ying. 2 vols. New York: Columbia University Press.

Dubs, Homer H. 1955. The History of the Former Han Dynasty . Baltimore: Waverly.

Dull, Jack L. 1978. "Marriage and Divorce in Han China: A Glimpse at 'Pre-Confucian' Society." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Ebrey, Patricia. 1981. "Women in the Kinship System of the Southern Song Upper Class." In Women in China , ed. Richard Guisso and Stanley Johannesen. Youngstown, N.Y.: Philo Press.

———. 1983. "Types of Lineages in Ch'ing China: A Re-examination of the Chang Lineage of T'ung-ch'eng." Ch'ing-shih wen-t'i 4.9:1-20.

———. 1984a. "Conceptions of the Family in the Sung Dynasty." Journal of Asian Studies 43. 2:219-45.

———. 1984b. Family and Property in Sung China: Yüan Ts'ai's Precepts for Social Life . Princeton: Princeton University Press.

———. 1986. "Concubines in Sung China." Journal of Family History 11.1:1-24.

Endicott-West, Elizabeth. 1986. "Imperial Governance in Yüan Times." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 46.2:523-49.

Fang, Achilles. 1952. The Chronicle of the Three Kingdoms . Vol. 1. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

———. 1965. The Chronicle of the Three Kingdoms . Vol. 2. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Feng, Han-i. 1948. The Chinese Kinship System . Cambridge: Harvard-Yenching Institute.

Fitzgerald, C. P. 1968. The Empress Wu . Melbourne, Canberra, and Sydney: F. W. Cheshire for the Australian National University.

Fletcher, Joseph. 1986. "The Mongols: Ecological and Social Perspectives." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 46.1:11-30.

Grafflin, Dennis. 1980. "Social Order in the Early Southern Dynasties: The Formation of Eastern Chin." Ph.D. diss., Harvard University.

———. 1981. "The Great Family in Medieval South China." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 41.1:63-74.

Greiner, Peter. 1979-80. "Die Frauen am Kaiserhof der Ming-Zeit" (Women at the Ming imperial court). Monumenta Serica 34:1-63.

Hartwell, Robert M. 1982. "Demographic, Political, and Social Transformations of China, 750-1550." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 42:365-442.

Holmgren, J. 1980. "Lineage Falsification in the Northern Dynasties: Wei Shou's Ancestry." Papers on Far Eastern History 21:1-16.


95

———. 1981 "Widow Chastity in the Northern Dynasties: The Lieh-nü Biographies in the Wei-shu. " Papers on Far Eastern History 23:165-86.

———. 1981-83a. "Social Mobility in the Northern Dynasties: A Case Study of the Feng of Northern Yen." Monumenta Serica 35:19-32.

———. 1981-83b. "Women and Political Power in the Traditional T'o-pa Elite: A Preliminary Study of the Biographies of Empresses in the Wei-shu. " Monumenta Seri-ca 35:33-73.

———. 1983a. "The Harem in Northern Wei Politics—398-498 A.D. " Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 26.1:71-96.

———. 1983b. "The Lu Clan of Tai Commandary and Their Contribution to the T'o-pan State of Northern Wei in the Fifth Century." T'oung pao 69.4-5:272-312.

———. 1983c. "Wei-shu Records on the Bestowal of Imperial Princesses during the Northern Wei Dynasty." Papers on Far Eastern History 27:21-97.

———. 1984. "The Making of an Elite: Local Politics and Social Relations in Northeastern China during the Fifth Century A.D. " Papers on Far Eastern History 30:1-79.

———. 1985. "The Economic Foundations of Virtue: Widow-Remarriage in Early and Modern China." Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 13:1-27.

———. 1986a. "Marriage, Kinship and Succession under the Ch'i-tan Rulers of the Liao Dynasty (907-1125)." T'oung pao 72:44-91.

———. 1986b. "Observations on Marriage and Inheritance Practices in Early Mongol and Yuan Society, with Particular Reference to the Levirate." Journal of Asian History 20.2:127-92.

———. 1986c. "Yeh-lü, Yao-lien and Ta-ho: Views of the Hereditary Prerogative in Early Khitan Leadership." Papers on Far Eastern History 34:37-81.

———. 1987. "Political Organization of Non-Han States in China: The Role of Imperial Princes in Wei, Liao and Yuan." Journal of Oriental Studies 25.1:1-48.

———. N.d. "A Question of Strength: Military Capability and Princess Bestowal in Imperial China's Foreign Relations (Han to Ch'ing)." Monumenta Serica (forthcoming).

Hymes, Robert P. 1986. Statesmen and Gentlemen: The Elite of Fu-chou, Chiang-hsi, in Northern and Southern Sung . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Johnson, Wallace. 1979. The T'ang Code . Vol. 1, General Principles . Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Kamada, Shigeo, 1962. "Han Emperors' Policy of Oppressing Kingdoms," Memoirs of the Research Department of the Toyo Bunko 21: 77-95.

Krader, Lawrence. 1963. Social Organization of the Mongol-Turkic Pastoral Nomads . Indiana University Publications, Uralic and Altaic Series, vol. 20. The Hague: Mouton.

Li Hsueh-ming (Lee Hok-ming) inline image. 1970. "Ts'ung Tung Han cheng-ch'üan shih-chih lun ch'i shih ti-shih hun-yin ssu-hsu yü wai-ch'i sheng-chiang chih kuan-hsi" inline image (The relationship between political power in Eastern [Later] Han and imperial marriage and succession and the mobility of distaff families). Hsin-ya hsueh-pao 9.2:225-82.

Loewe, Michael. 1974. Crisis and Conflict in Han China . London: George Allen & Unwin.

Sang Hsiu-yun inline image. 1969. "Chin-shih Wan-yen shih hun-chih chih shih-shih"


96

figure
(A tentative study of the marriage system of the imperial Wan-yen clan during the Chin dynasty). Bulletin of the Institute of History and Philolo gy (Academia Sinica) 39.1:255-88.

Schurmann, H. F. 1955—56. "Traditional Property Concepts in China." Far Eastern Quarterly 15:507-16.

Shiga, Shuzo. 1978. "Family Property and the Law of Inheritance in Traditional China." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Soullière, Ellen F. 1984. "Reflections on Chinese Despotism and the Power of the Inner Court." Asian Profile 12.2:130-45.

———. 1987. "Palace Women in the Ming Dynasty." Ph.D. diss., Princeton University.

———. 1988. "The Imperial Marriages of the Ming Dynasty." Papers on Far Eastern History 37:15-42.

Straughair, Anna. 1973. Chang Hua: A Statesman-Poet of the Chin Dynasty . Occasional Paper 15. Canberra: Australian National University, Faculty of Asian Studies.

Sung Te-chin inline image. 1982. "Chin-tai Nü-chen tsu su shu-lun" inline image (Jurchen customs in the Chin). Li-shih yen-chiu , no. 3:145-59.

Tai Yen-hui. 1978. "Divorce in Traditional Chinese Law." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Tang, Karen Kai-ying. 1975. "Empress Wei, Consort Shang-kuan and the Political Conflicts in the Reign of Chung-tsung." M.A. thesis, University of British Columbia.

Tao Tien-yi. 1974. "Vassal Kings and Marquises of the Former Han Dynasty." Bulletin of the Institute of History and Philology (Academia Sinica) 46.1:155-72.

———. 1978. "The System of Imperial Succession during China's Former Han Dynasty (206 B.C. -9 A.D. )." Papers on Far Eastern History 18:171-91.

Tjan, Tjoe Som. 1949, 1952. Reprint, 1973. Po Hu T'ung: The Comprehensive Discussions in the White Tiger Hall . 2 vols. Westport, Conn.: Hyperion Press.

Wallacker, Benjamin E. 1987. "Dethronement and Due Process in Early Imperial China." Journal of Asian History 21.1:48-67.

Waltner, Ann Beth. 1981. "The Adoption of Children in Ming and Early Ch'ing China." Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley.

Walton, Linda. 1984. "Kinship, Marriage and Status in Song China: A Study of the Lou Lineage of Ningbo, c. 1050-1250." Journal of Asian History 18.1:35-77.

Ward-Czynska, Bonnie V. 1978. "A Political History of the Imperial Distaff Relatives of the Former Han Dynasty." M.A. thesis, Columbia University.

Wittfogel, K. A., and Feng Chia-sheng. 1949. History of Chinese Society. Liao . Philadelphia: American Philosophical Society.

Wong Sun-ming. 1979. "Confucian Ideal and Reality: Transformation of the Institution of Marriage in T'ang China." Ph.D. diss., University of Washington.

Yang Lien-sheng. 1968. "Female Rulers in Imperial China." In Studies of Governmental Institutions in Chinese History , ed. John L. Bishop. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Young, Gregory C. 1986. "Court Politics in the Later Han: Officials and the Consort Clan, A.D. 132-44." Papers on Far Eastern History 34:1-36.


97

Three
Shifts in Marriage Finance from the Sixth to the Thirteenth Century

Patricia Buckley Ebrey

People in the T'ang period [A.D. 618-907] celebrated the Ts'uis and Lus as top-rank families. Even when descendants of these families were poor and of low political rank, they were esteemed for their pedigree. Today people do not make much of family. Ira girt of a noble family is poor and without resources, she may not be able to marry in her prime. Yet village rich families can marry into noble houses and get those who passed the examinations in the top group as their sons-in-law.
CHAO YEN-WEI, 1206 (YLMC 3:98)


A marriage in China, as in most places, normally involved some financial outlay by both the husband's and the wife's families and therefore some redistribution of wealth. In the classical ritual prescriptions preserved in the I-li (Etiquette and Ritual), the husband's family would send a goose to the wife's family on several occasions, and midway between the first proposal and the wedding itself the groom's family sent more substantial gifts, given in the I-li as ten bolts of cloth and a pair of deer skins (Steele 1917 1:18-23). The bride's family was not obliged to present gifts to the groom's family, but the bride herself would be sent with clothes and personal items such as jewelry packed in cases, and could be supplied with female attendants who might serve as her maids or her husband's concubines (see also Thatcher's chapter here for exchanges between ruling families). In early texts these two types of outlays are generally treated as belonging to different realms. The gifts presented by the husband's family fell into the realm of ritual. Presenting and accepting these gifts was integral to the betrothal ceremony: one was not married ritually without some token transfer of objects from the groom's family to the bride's. The classic Li chi (Record of Ritual) asserts: "Without receipt of the betrothal gifts there is no contact and no affinity" (cf. Legge 1885 1:78). In later periods, at least, once betrothal gifts had been received, the girl's family could be prosecuted if they broke off the engagement (TLSI 13:119). By contrast, the validity of a marriage did not depend on the bride's bringing anything. Nor were the objects she brought termed gifts; they were simply her possessions. By the Han period (902 B.C.-A.D. 220) there is scat-


98

tered evidence that how well a bride was equipped depended on how much her family wished to do for her, which in turn probably depended on how rich they were, how many sons they had, the importance they placed on the match, and probably sometimes the affection they felt for her. When either family was rich, they could make their outlays in style, giving generous gifts and supplying daughters with handsome dowries. A girl without brothers, as heiress, could receive the bulk of the family property as her dowry (see Yang 1933:17-19; Dull 1978:45-48).

In this chapter my concern is not with heiresses or routine marriage exchanges of modest size, but with marriage outlays that made a substantial economic difference to the two families. Demands for lavish betrothal gifts began to be heard among aristocratic families from the late fifth century on; a few centuries later demands for substantial dowries were made by the families of the Sung (960-1279) upper class. The motivations for these marriages were by no means simply economic; the marriages sealed with these transfers of property brought prestige and connections to affines. I therefore try to show how the tangible financial benefits and less tangible benefits of honor and connections worked together in these two periods. I also explain how the shift in the balance of marriage finance related to the changed political and economic environment of the ruling elite.

Marriage Finance Among Aristocratic Families, Sixth-Ninth Centuries

After the fall of the Han dynasty, Chinese society developed in distinctly aristocratic directions. By the late fourth century in the south and the late fifth century in the north, a relatively small number of families were preeminent in social and political life. Along with admiration for aristocratic pedigrees came an inflation in the value of the betrothal gifts the highest-ranking families could expect to receive when they sent out a daughter in marriage. In the south in about 490 Shen Yueh accused Wang Yuan of highly objectionable behavior. Wang had married his daughter to a man of much lower social status who had paid a "betrothal gift" (p'in-li ) of fifty thousand cash. Wang made enough of a profit from this transaction to buy himself a concubine (WH 40:879-81; cf. Johnson 1977:9-11). A few decades later in his "Family Instructions," Yen Chih-t'ui (531-c. 591) complained that such transactions were all too common:

In the present age, when marriages are arranged, some people sell their daughters for the betrothal gift or buy a wife by making a payment of silk. They compare the ancestry [of the two parties], calculate down to the smallest sum, demand much and offer little, exactly like bargaining in a market. As a result coarse sons-in-law may enter the family or arrogant daughters-in-law take over the house. ( YSCH 1:64; cf. Teng 1968:20)


99

Note that Yen's complaint resembles Shen Yueh's: Those who had daughters profited, while those who needed wives would have to pay. Such conditions meant that girls from families with the most esteemed ancestry were marrying down. They seemed arrogant to their in-laws, while their husbands seemed coarse to their parents. Cross-culturally, marriage exchanges have often been compared to commercial transactions, so this does not necessarily mean that marriages were in some objective sense more like "sales" in this period (Comaroff 1980:40-41). What was probably new was the size of the betrothal gifts and weight assigned to ancestry, not the negotiation process itself.[1]

Yen Chih-t'ui implied that an eminent family could expect an even higher sum if they married their daughter into a family of lesser birth. Indeed, Yang Su (d. 606), perhaps the most powerful official of the early Sui (581-618), gave "extremely generous" betrothal gifts so that his son could marry the daughter of Ts'ui Piao, a Ch'ing-ho Ts'ui of eminent ancestry whose "family standing" (men-ti ) he valued. Yang even put up with rude behavior on the part of Ts'ui Piao to bring the marriage about (SuiS 76:1733). Something of the size of an "extremely generous" betrothal gift can be imagined from the case of a Northern Ch'i (550-77) official who got into trouble because he embezzled 400,000 cash to pay for the betrothal gift for marriage to the daughter of a T'ai-yuan Wang (PCS 42:564). In this period, betrothal gifts could include fields and animals. One Northern Ch'i official known for his stinginess was accused of sending inferior items as parts of the betrothal gift when his son married a Fan-yang Lu girl. These items were lame mules, infertile fields, and secondhand brass vessels (PCS 43:573).

Further evidence of the size of betrothal gifts can be found in the sumptuary rules issued to regulate them. In the late fifth and sixth centuries, the various governments tried to fight persistent tendencies for prestige to become independent of the ranks and honors emanating from the court. For instance, governments in both the north and the south tried to control the publication of genealogical gazetteers that ranked families (see Johnson 1977b:33-43). When the ability to command large betrothal gifts became a sign of high status beyond the government's power to control, the Northern Ch'i government promulgated rules to make these gifts correspond to political rank. At each of the "six rites" (i.e., the steps in betrothal), everyone with rank (from the emperor down to rank-nine officials) could present a lamb, a pair of geese, and a hu each of wine, millet, rice, and flour. Commoners could present gifts half this large. For the betrothal gift, much more detailed specifications were given for five kinds of cloth and a variety of foodstuffs, varying in quantities according to official rank. For instance, the highest officials could give 140 pieces of plain silk (chüan ), the lowest officials 34 (SuiS 9:179). Clearly by this time gifts of much greater monetary value than anything prescribed in the classics were commonly exchanged at weddings of aristocrats and other wealthy officials.


100

Even though substantial betrothal gifts received imperial approval as long as they were in line with official rank, negotiating their size was never deemed morally correct in the Confucian view of marriage. Wang T'ung (c. 584-617), a Confucian teacher, wrote: "Discussing wealth in arranging a marriage is the way of the barbarians," a saying frequently quoted by later writers (CS 1:11). He probably suspected that this practice—unattested in the classics—was the legacy of the non-Han rulers of the Northern dynasties (386-581). More likely, it reflects the growth of aristocracy.

In 632, after the founding of the T'ang dynasty (618-906), Emperor T'ai-tsung reiterated Yen Chih-t'ui's complaint about mercenary marriage arrangements. The emperor directed his remarks specifically against the leading families of the northeast (the Ts'uis, Lus, Lis, and Chengs), who were arrogant in their assumption of superior birth. He charged that "every time they marry out a daughter to another family they demand a large betrothal gift (p'in-ts'ai ), taking quantity to be the important thing. They discuss numbers and settle an agreement, just like merchants in the market" (CKCY 7:226). Six years later T'ai-tsung chastised his own officials for their lack of self-respect, evident in their vying for marriage into these families out of "admiration for their ancestry (tsu-tsung )." Even when they presented valuable betrothal gifts, the officials' families accepted a position of inferiority vis-à-vis their affinal relatives and thus had to tolerate disrespectful behavior from their daughters-in-law (CKCY 7:227).

In 657 the next emperor, Kao-tsung, complained again about the snobbish exclusiveness underlying the leading families' marriage practices. He took several measures designed to curb them. First he prohibited marriage among eleven lines of seven old families of five surnames.[2] Limits were also set on how much wealth a family could receive in the form of betrothal gifts when marrying out a daughter. These limits were three hundred pieces of silk for families rank three or higher, two hundred for rank four and five, one hundred for rank six and seven, and fifty for anyone lower. (Because in this period silk was commonly used as a currency, the intention probably was that all the gifts given should not exceed these values, rather than that only silk should be used for the gifts.) Finally, he restricted the use of betrothal gifts: the bride's family was not to make a profit by marrying a daughter out but was to use all of the betrothal gifts to supply her dowry, and her husband's family was not to appropriate the dowry either (THY 83:1528-29). In other words, families could expend handsome sums only so long as they were seen as outfitting the bride; neither family could then be interpreted as seeking a profit or "selling" a bride.

As several scholars have shown, the highest level of the T'ang elite was very largely drawn from family lines well established in earlier dynasties (Twitchett 1973; Johnson 1977b; and Ebrey 1978). In this period, pedigree


101

did not confer automatic access to office, yet a relatively small group of old families managed to do extraordinarily well in placing their sons in office through their traditions of education, success in examinations, use of "protection" privilege, reputation for correct behavior, and so on. Endogamous marriage practices were crucial in sustaining the concept of an aristocracy of "old families." In the case of the Po-ling Ts'uis, of ninety-two marriages during the T'ang, 52 percent were with others of the "seven old families," another 30 percent were with the other twenty-two old families identified by Liu Fang in the mid-eighth century as "aristocratic," and all but two of the others with the hundred-odd families listed in genealogical gazetteers of the most eminent families in the country (Ebrey 1978:94-96).

Among the T'ang elite, it was the larger "family," or patriline, of the marriage partners that mattered most (Johnson 1977b:59-60; Ebrey 1978: 94-100). That is, men could plausibly assert that it was more prestigious to marry a daughter of one of the "seven old families" than to marry the daughter of a current chief minister or even a princess. A minister in the late seventh century who had married an imperial princess is said to have lamented that he had neither gained the chin-shih degree nor married a daughter of one of the "five surnames" ( TYL 4:140). In the eighth century a T'ai-yuan Wang woman who married a Po-ling Ts'ui (both among the "seven old families," or "five surnames") was praised for selecting spouses from the northeastern families rather than from the "powerful" for her offspring. She had married one son to her brother's daughter and the other to a Fan-yang Lu girl (Ebrey 1978:95, 183, 184). An early ninth-century emperor could complain that people paid attention only to pedigree and not to official rank in selecting marriage partners (HTS 172:5206). Even as late as the first half of the tenth century, a Lung-hsi Li was praised for not being arrogant like others in his "family," or the Ts'ui, Lu, and Cheng "families" with whom his family intermarried. Members of these families would only agree to marry a girl into another family after receiving "generous presents of gold and silk" (CWTS 93:1230).[3]

Exclusivity reaffirms prestige. By marrying their peers, households belonging to the highest levels of the aristocracy were confirming their status. Households of aristocratic descent that were not prospering financially or. politically were making use of their best resource, pedigree, when they married peers or accepted large betrothal gifts to marry others. Families that were "buying in" by taking a bride of higher status than their own were making a long-term investment in the status of their grandchildren. This was possible because pedigree through mothers was considered in assessing family standing. A ninth-century epitaph noted that although the subject's immediate patrilineal ancestors had undistinguished careers, "their relatives through marriage were the top families in the northeast" (CTW 504:9b).


102

This concern for maternal pedigree may explain why the ambitious are portrayed as seeking, not aristocratic sons-in-law, but aristocratic daughters-in-law who would be the mothers of their grandchildren.

The affinal relations created by these aristocratic marriages were conceived in general terms. The statement that "our families have intermarried for generations" or "we have old marriage connections" was often used to evoke the notion of affinal relationship: the individual so addressed might not have any close current tie. For instance, Li Hua (fl. 740s), a Chao-chün Li, said he had called on a Po-ling Ts'ui, as their families were from "adjoining areas in the northern prefectures and had old marriage ties" (CTW 315:7a). The man he was calling on had never lived in the northeast himself, and the visit undoubtedly took place in one of the capitals, Ch'ang-an or Lo-yang. The marriage ties seem to have been just as distant.

In the T'ang, thus, betrothal gifts among the aristocratic families were of great monetary value and were linked to marital exclusivity and the preservation of a tiny super-elite. By marrying so disproportionately among themselves, the aristocrats showed that they believed their own claims to superiority and did not rate wealth or government title above pedigree or refinement. T'ang complaints about the size of the betrothal gifts of aristocrats almost always stressed the snobbishness involved. It was not that the old families willingly gave their daughters to whoever came up with the most money. Rather they were so reluctant to marry with anyone but their own kind that outsiders had to go to extraordinary lengths if they wished to penetrate their circle.

Marriage Finance in the Sung

By the Sung period (960-1279), the balance in marriage finance had changed so that wives' families, especially among the upper class, had larger net outlays than husbands' families. No survey of marriage institutions in Chinese history points out this fundamental change (see Ch'en 1936; Ch'ü 1965; Holmgren 1985; Lü 1935; Ma 1981; and T'ao 1966). Yet I am convinced it occurred because of evidence of six sorts: (1) complaints about mercenary marriages put more stress on men seeking large dowries; (2) people drew up detailed lists of dowries before concluding marriages; (3) the legal code was revised to protect a daughter's claims to a dowry if her father died before she was married; (4) biographies of women much more frequently mention their possession of substantial dowries; (5) discussions of family budgeting treat provision of daughters' dowries as a major family expense; and (6) the cost of dowry came to be recognized as a major problem even among ordinary people. Before reviewing this evidence, I should acknowledge that sources of all kinds survive in greater abundance for the Sung than the T'ang, making arguments based on the silence of T'ang sources weak.


103

Therefore, I give greatest weight to cases where the T'ang sources say something, but what they say is different from what Sung sources say.

Complaints about Mercenary Marriages

I have already reviewed T'ang complaints about mercenary marriages. Wife-giving families snobbishly demanded large betrothal gifts. In the Sung there were just as many complaints about marriage being treated like a transaction, with bargaining and contracts (cf. Fang 1986). However, the issue was no longer simply the betrothal gift and its return as dowry, but the wife's family's contribution. The value of the dowry was often much larger than that of the betrothal gifts, so that the wife's family had made a major contribution to the new couple's economic foundations. Indeed, Sung dowries often included land.

One of the first signs of the escalation in the size of dowries is a reference to a tax imposed on them by one of the minor states in the tenth century, the Later Shu (934-65), which controlled the Szechwan area (CP 14:305). By the mid-eleventh century something of a dowry crisis appears to have emerged among the upper class.

Ts'ai Hsiang (1012-67), while prefect of Fu-chou (Fukien) in the 1050s, posted a notice pointing out that "the purpose of marriage is to produce heirs, not to acquire wealth." Instead of recognizing this truth, he charged, people ignored family status (men-hu ) in choosing brides, their minds entirely on the dowry. Once the dowry was delivered to the groom's home, "they inspect the dowry cases, in the morning searching through one, in the evening another. The husband cruelly keeps making more and more demands on his wife. If he is not satisfied, it can spoil their love or even lead to divorce. This custom has persisted for so long that people accept it as normal" (SWC 108:1439). Note how Ts'ai would like to return to some vaguely conceived former system where men sought family status in brides, not just wealth.

Ssu-ma Kuang (1019-86) a few years later provided a similar depiction of the pressures created by demands for dowries:

Nowadays it is the custom for covetous and vulgar people first to ask about the value of the dowry when selecting a bride and the amount of the betrothal gift when marrying a daughter. Some even draw up a contract saying "such goods, in such numbers, such goods, in such numbers," thereby treating their daughters as an item in a sales transaction. There are also cases where people go back on their agreements after the wedding is over. These are the methods used by brokers dealing in male and female bondservants. How can such a transaction be called a gentleman-official (shih-ta-fu ) marriage?

When parents-in-law have been deceived, they will maltreat the daughter-in-law as a way to vent their fury. Fearing this, parents who love their daughter put together a generous dowry in the hope of pleasing her parents-in-law, not


104

realizing that such covetous vulgar people are insatiable. When the dowry is depleted, what use will the bride be to these parents-in-law? They will then "pawn" her to get further payment from her family. Her family's wealth has a limit, but their demands will never stop. Therefore, families linked by marriage often end up enemies. (SMSSI 3:33)

Ssu-ma Kuang mentions both dowry and betrothal gifts as open to negotiation, but seems to see the greater problem with dowry (perhaps because betrothal gifts were returned as part of the dowry). Particularly troublesome was the problem of parents-in-law mistreating the bride if her dowry were smaller than they had been led to expect. Moreover, they might make new demands on her parents, which the latter felt obliged to meet because their daughter's welfare was at stake. The situation sounds more reminiscent of India in recent times than the world of Yen Chih-t'ui and T'ang T'ai-tsung. A century later this dowry crisis had still not abated, for Yuan Ts'ai (c. 1140-95) could argue that if a family did not begin planning for their daughter's dowry when she was very young, they would have to "sell land or buildings as temporary expedients, or callously watch [their] daughter's humiliation in front of others" (Ebrey 1984b:266).

Other Sung accusations about mercenary marriages inverted the complaints of Yen Chih-t'ui and T'ang T'ai-tsung in yet another way. It was not daughters with desirable ancestry going to the highest bidders, but men with good career potential. Ting Chih (c. 1060) wrote:

Your subject has heard that in recent years after a chin-shih passes the examination, he discusses wealth before taking a bride, in full violation of ritual and morality. Families of officials, depending on how wealthy they are, send go-betweens back and forth, sometimes almost begging. If anything is not quite to his liking [the new chin-shih ] casts them aside and goes to another family. (SWC 61:852-53)

Apparently what these new chin-shih wanted were daughters of officials who would bring generous dowries. Similar comments were made by Chu Yü (c. 1075-1119):

In our dynasty the families of high-ranking men select their sons-in-law during the years of the metropolitan examinations, choosing from among the scholars who attend. They do not inquire into yin and yang or auspiciousness, nor into ancestry (chia-shih ). This practice is called "seizing a son-in-law from under the lists." Strings of cash called "money for tying the one seized" are given to the prospective groom for his expenses in the capital. In recent years rich merchants, the vulgar, and those who have great savings also "seize a son-in-law from under the lists" when they arrange a marriage for a daughter. They make the "seizing money" generous in order to entice scholars to condescend to come. One son-in-law can cost over a thousand strings. When the wedding


105

takes place, his family also demands "money all around" [a kind of tipping]. Often they calculate what is in the cases and sacks and want an agreement tied up like a legal document. (PCKT 1:16)

In this case dowry (the contents of the cases and sacks) is only a part of the transaction. The girl's family has also given money directly to the future son-in-law for his "expenses," apparently a kind of earnest given to the man himself.

The type of bidding for sons-in-law that Ting Chih and Chu Yü criticized is confirmed in Sung biographies. For instance, the biography of Feng Ching (1021-94) reports that when he passed the metropolitan examination in first place in 1049 he was still not married. Chang Yao-tso (987-1058), then powerful at court because a niece was the emperor's favorite consort, wanted Feng to marry his daughter; he gave him a gold belt and on another occasion brought out a list of her dowry. Feng refused the match, conceivably because he thought he could do better: he ended up marrying the daughter of Fu Pi (1004-83), a much more influential patron (SS 317:10338-39).[4] A similar case is mentioned in the epitaphs for Chiang Pao (1069-1117) and his wife. After Chiang received the chin-shih at twenty-five or twenty-six sui , the high official Tseng Pu (1035-1107) proposed marriage to his daughter by a concubine along with a gift of 300,000 cash. Chiang reportedly declined the gift but accepted the marriage proposal (PSHC 13:4a; 13b-14a).

Let me give one final quotation. Yuan Ts'ai, writing in l178, referred to mercenary marriages in the context of the deceptions of matchmakers. As he noted, the classical complaint was that matchmakers fooled the girl's family by saying the boy was rich and the boy's family by saying the girl was beautiful. In his own time their chicanery focused on money matters: "Matchmakers deceive the girl's family by saying the boy does not seek a full complement of dowry presents and in fact will help in outfitting the bride. They deceive the boy's family by promising generous transfer of goods, and they make up a figure without any basis in fact" (Ebrey 1984b:223). Here the whole issue is dowry: the bride's family is told it can be small and come from indirect dowry; the boy's family is assured it will be large.

In comparing T'ang and Sung complaints about marriage payments, differences in the meaning assigned to these payments are striking. Snobbishness and exclusivity were regularly attributed to those who demanded large betrothal gifts in the T'ang, lack of self-respect to those who consented. In the Sung, social exclusivity was not associated with large dowries. Families insisting that a large dowry accompany daughters-in-law were not suspected of erecting status barriers to keep lowborn women out of their homes. Men who sought large dowries were accused of greed, not disdain for those below them. The ulterior motive of a family offering a handsome dowry was gener-


106

ally assumed to be a desire to attach to them a young man of promise, rather than more diffuse links to a famous family. Indeed, a concern with family pedigree was contrasted to a concern with dowries.[5]

Marriage Agreements

Ssu-ma Kuang's charge that people drew up contracts specifying betrothal gifts and dowries can easily be confirmed in other Sung sources, though most of the time the term "contract" (ch'i-yueh ) was avoided. Sung marriage agreements were much more detailed than anything surviving from the T'ang.[6] The Meng liang lu (Record of Dreams of Glory), which describes the Southern Sung (1127-1279) capital of Hangchow, reported that an "agreement card" (ting-t'ieh ) sent by the man's family would list the son's birth order in the family (first, second, or third son, and so on); the year, month, day, and hour of his birth; whether his parents were living, and, if not, who was presiding over the marriage; and, in the event that the marriage was uxorilocal, the wealth he would bring in "gold and silver, fields, productive property (ts'ai-ch'an ), houses, rooms, hills, and gardens." The card that the girl's family returned would likewise give her seniority number and time of birth, then list what she was bringing, her "cases with jewelry, gold and silver, pearls and feathers, precious objects, items for use, and bedding, as well as the property accompanying her on her marriage, such as fields, houses, businesses, hills, or gardens" (MLL 20:304). In other words, dowry was specified in the first proposal, as was the man's "dowry" if he were to be an uxorilocal husband.

Sung guides to letter-writing often devoted several chapters to marriage correspondence. Like the Meng liang lu , these books show the dowry to be specified in the first proposal. In the next round of communications, lists of betrothal gifts were often attached to the "engagement letter" (hun-shu ) sent by the groom's family.[7] The bride's family sent back comparable letters, including a list of the betrothal gifts they were refusing as well as a list of the objects in the trousseau (CCCC 489-90; SLKC ch'ien-chi 10:5a-b; HLPY 1; HMTC chia 5:2a-4b). One of these books explained the difference between the items of the dowry specified on these two occasions: the "agreement card" would list the "major numbers" of land and servants, while the "trousseau list" would give the "minor numbers" of the various items of cloth, jewelry, and other goods sent "to make up the room" (HMTC i 18:6b).[8]

A Sung agreement card and trousseau list survive for the marriage of the daughter of a prominent family in K'un-shan county (Kiangsu). Dated 1261, the agreement card divides her dowry into three items: five hundred mou of land, trousseau (lien-chü ) of (or worth) eleven thousand strings of cash, and "marriage ties" (ti-yin ) of (or worth) five thousand strings.[9] In the trousseau list, dated fourteen months later, there is a detailed breakdown of different types of cloth and miscellaneous objects (STJC 8:4a-5b).


107

Revision of the Law Code

A third sign of the increased weight given dowry in the Sung is revision of the laws for division of family property so that orphaned daughters were provided with dowries. Neither the T'ang nor the Sung government concerned itself with the decisions a father made about the property to assign his daughter as dowry, nor did they routinely interfere with the decisions of other family seniors in undivided families. But orphans posed special problems. Stories and anecdotes often refer to the plight of orphaned daughters without dowries, even daughters from official families. It was taken for granted that their lack of a dowry would make it impossible for them to be married into an otherwise appropriate family, and might even lead to them being sold as concubines (Ebrey 1986a:6). Probably because of the disastrous consequences of daughters left without dowries, Sung law provided them some protection from the greed of brothers, uncles, and other potential heirs when the family property was divided.[10]

Already in the T'ang, if brothers who were dividing the property included one not yet married, or if they had unmarried sisters (or aunts), marriage expenses were to be set aside before the group property was divided. Unmarried brothers were to be given the funds for a betrothal gift in addition to their share, and unmarried sisters were to get marriage funds half the size of their brothers' funds (SHT 12:12b). This law was probably intended to codify practice in the T'ang, when the man's family gave betrothal gifts that cost more than the net outlay of the bride's family. The code said nothing about the appropriate size of betrothal gifts, but because this provision came into play only when at least one of the brothers was already married, funds similar to those used for the married brother(s) would probably be considered fair.

Later the law was revised to match Sung custom more closely, for Southern Sung judges cited rules that gave unmarried daughters more substantial dowries. Three particular changes in the law are noteworthy. First, at division unmarried daughters were to be assigned a share, or portion, half that of a son's share (i.e., half the size of his share of the estate, not half the size of the allotment for his marriage expenses) (CMC 8:290-91; HTHS 193:7a, 14a). This would mean that in families where a boy and two girls survived, none yet married, the boy would get half the property and each girl a quarter. Second, an old T'ang rule was revised. When a house died out (hu-chueh ) for lack of an established heir, the property had gone entirely to the unmarried daughters (or, in their absence, married daughters). This law was revised to reduce the amount going to married daughters (who already had dowries)[11] and was extended to cover cases where a man in an undivided family died leaving only daughters. The revised law stipulated that his daughters could succeed to his share of the property just as though the house had died out (e.g., CMC 8:280-82). Third, when an heir was set up post-


108

humously, he would not be treated like a natural son or an adoptive son set up during the parents' lifetimes, whose presence would eliminate shares for married daughters and significantly reduce those for unmarried daughters (as seems to have been the case in the T'ang). Instead, the property would be divided, with one-fourth to the posthumous heir and three-fourths to the unmarried daughters (if there were also married daughters, he would get one-fifth, if only married daughters, he would receive a third [CMC 8:266-67; HTHS 193:11a]). (On all of these revisions, see Burns 1973:259-81.) These changes in the law seem clearly to reflect the much greater weight dowry had come to play in the transmission of property between mid-T'ang and mid-Sung. T'ang law left it up to the heirs to decide how to provide for their sisters, aunts, or nieces no matter what the circumstances. It made no difference if the heir was an adoptee or if the property was under the trusteeship of a widowed concubine who was not the mother of the daughters, or under the trusteeship of an uncle, and so on. Sung law saw unmarried girls' need for dowries to be great enough to warrant some legal protection from unscrupulous relatives.

When judges supervised the division of an estate, they did not always follow these rules as they were codified, but they usually made substantial provisions for dowries. For instance, in the Ch'ing-ming chi , there is an account of a man who died, leaving behind two daughters, the elder nine sui . A posthumous heir was appointed for him. Rather than giving a quarter to the heir and three-eighths to each daughter (as the statutes specified), the judge gave each one-third, with the daughters' property earmarked for their dowries (CMC 7:215). In a case decided by Hu Ying (chin-shih 1232), one of three brothers died before their property had been divided, leaving a single daughter (his wife was also dead). An earlier official had said the daughter should get one-third of what would normally go to her father, but Hu Ying revised this to half on the grounds that she had not been married when her father died and a girl should get half as much as a son, who would have received it all. Moreover, Hu Ying said that all of the private property of the girl's father's branch (such as her mother's dowry) was to go to her (CMC 8:280-82). In a case decided by Liu K'o-chuang (1187-1269), family property was first divided into two collateral lines. In one line, a brother got half and his two sisters each a quarter. In the other, a posthumous heir and two natural daughters each got a quarter, the remaining quarter to be used for the funeral expenses of the girls' father (HTHS 193:10a-17b).

One can also find cases where orphaned daughters received smaller shares. Judges took into account a variety of circumstances: fathers specifying a smaller share in the will, mothers remarrying and taking their daughters with them, or the presence of a step-mother or adopted brother (e.g., CMC 5:141-42, 7:230-32, 238-39). But the direction of the change in the law was undoubtedly to protect orphaned girls' claims to property for dowry.


109

References to Dowry in Epitaphs and Anecdotes

In T'ang epitaphs for women, references to their dowries are rare.[12] By contrast, they are fairly common in Sung epitaphs.[13] For instance, in the early eleventh century a woman from a rich official family married a man who passed the examinations at seventeen, the first in his family to have an official career that they knew of. According to her epitaph, she felt uncomfortable at having so much private property (ssu-ts'ai ) when her husband's family was poor, and so contributed it all to the common pool (KSC 53:646). In the early twelfth century the daughter of an official married an orphan who had just passed the examinations. It happened that one of her husband's relatives had sold the hill with the ancestral graves on it to a temple. The husband was about to borrow money to try to redeem the hill when his wife stopped him and said: "The reason my parents sent me with property was to be of aid to your family. How could I use it while your family graves are not being preserved?" She emptied out her chests to redeem the hill and with the remainder bought more land and built a building on it for the protection of the graveyard (NCCIK 22:459). In a similar case recorded in another epitaph, some brothers were about to sell part of the family land to pay for their father's funeral. One of their wives insisted they should keep the ancestral property intact; she would give them what they 'needed from her dowry (CWKWC 91:14a). The epitaph for a woman who in 1160 married into a family with less than three mu of land reports that she told her husband that his land might be enough for the present but that they needed to increase it to plan for their descendants. Consequently, when a neighbor wanted to sell his land, she quickly sold the land she had brought as dowry in order to buy the neighbor's property and gave the deed to her father-in-law (CCC 12:254-55). Another epitaph records that a woman in the mid-twelfth century sold five mu of her dowry land to supply the money needed for her husband's brother to get a second wife after his first had died (YSC 14:263). Epitaphs might also praise a woman for her generosity in willing her dowry; one reported that a woman asked that her dowry be distributed to all the children arid grandchildren in the family (LCC 28:14a).

These epitaphs were written by men who did not fully approve of wives' treating dowry as private property.[14] The women are portrayed as willingly using all or part of their dowries for larger family purposes, such as ancestral rites, funerals, or marriages of the husband's siblings, thus testifying to their commitment to the solidarity of the family. Indeed, these epitaphs may reasonably be used to infer that most women guarded their dowries with vigilance and never lost sight of the difference between their own property and the larger family's. Liu Tsai (1166-1239), for instance, noted that women by nature are tightfisted, thus making the woman he was writing about exceptional: she not only turned over all of her ample dowry and dowry


110

fields to her husband, but she also never asked for an accounting of the income or expenses (MTC 34:18b).

Evidence of the Relative Cost of Dowry and Betrothal Gifts

Not only did dowries come to be substantial, but providing them also proved a more onerous burden than meeting a son's wedding expenses. Yuan Ts'ai mentioned three expenses for which families should plan long in advance: sons' educations, daughters' marriages, and parents' funerals. If a family took adequate steps—such as planting ten thousand pine trees at each daughter's birth—they would not need to worry that their daughters would "miss the best time" (Ebrey 1984b:266).

Numerical estimates of the relative costs of marriages are found in some rules for distributing income. The rules for the Fan lineage's charitable estate, formulated in 1050, specified that when a daughter was married out, thirty strings of cash were granted; twenty if it were her second marriage. When a son took a first wife twenty strings were supplied, but none for a second. These figures are on the order of the grants for funerals; the funerals of seniors were subsidized with twenty-five strings, of juniors fifteen, and of children, from two to ten strings depending on age (Twitchett 1960:9). Lü Tsu-ch'ien (1137-81), in rules he wrote up for an undivided family, specified that one hundred strings be given when a daughter was marrying and fifty when a son was marrying (LTLWC 10:243). A charitable venture set up in 1199 in Kwangtung for the dependents of officials who died there provided that five strings of cash be given to help in the marriage of daughters, but only three strings for the marriage of a son or a funeral (SHY shih-huo 60:1a-b).[15] Although each of these sets of rules stipulates different levels of funding, in each case parents of daughters were given 50 to 100 percent more than parents of sons.

Dowry in Lower Social Levels

Substantial dowries, in Sung times, were not confined to the families of officials. Memorialists sometimes complained that demands for excessively large dowries were making it impossible for girls to marry, or were forcing their families to sell land or borrow money to pay for them (e.g., SHY hsing-fa 2:154-55). One official even attributed female infanticide to the high cost of dowries (CYIL 117:1889). Hou K'o (1007-79), while magistrate of Hua-ch'eng (Szechwan), found that many girls grew old without marrying because "When people of Pa take wives they always demand property from the girl's family." His solution was to make up a schedule for dowries according to the wealth of the family and to set punishments for anyone who exceeded it. Within a year, we are told, every spinster had been married out (ECC wen-chi 4:504). Sun Chueh (1028-90) found a similar situation in Fu-chou (Fukien) and simply issued an order that dowries were not to exceed one hundred


111

strings of cash, which promptly led to several hundred weddings (SS 344:10927). Chu Hsi (1130-1200) found that in southern Fukien girls were sent to Buddhist cloisters in part because their parents did not have the money for their marriage expenses (CWKWC 100:4a-5b). In these cases the clear implication is that dowry was a severe problem even among ordinary people. One Sung observer, commenting on the customs in the far south, noted that there poor girls of fourteen or fifteen worked to earn their own dowries so that their families would not have a single cash of expense (CLP 2:52). Clearly he expected his readers to understand the problem of providing dowries among the poor.

That dowries could be large among ordinary people is confirmed in cases in the Ch'ing-ming chi . Judges never registered surprise that families neither wealthy nor well educated would give land as part of daughters' dowries. Anecdotal evidence suggests that men from families with modest means could get larger dowries if they accepted a widow, a woman who had been a concubine or courtesan, or if they entered the woman's household as the uxorilocal husband of a girl or widow. For instance, a petty trader whose wife had died in an epidemic took as his second wife a former concubine with a dowry of three hundred strings (ICC san-pu 1807). Moreover, even modest dowries might be useful. In another anecdote, a dog butcher's wife brought a dowry worth several dozen strings of cash, which was used as business capital. At one point the husband sold a pair of silver hairpins from it to buy dogs to slaughter; later when he wanted to abandon the business on Buddhist grounds, his wife said that her trunks still had several bolts of cloth that they could use as capital for some new means of supporting themselves (ICC pu 3:1574-75).

If there were only one type of evidence indicating that the balance in marriage finance had shifted between T'ang and Sung, one might suspect that the change was historiographical rather than historical. References to substantial dowries could appear more often in Sung epitaphs because writers wished to give more concrete examples of women's virtues, for instance. The law could have been revised to take account of customary practices that had been in existence for many centuries. Differences in the types of marriages referred to as mercenary could be accidental, the result of the chance survival of certain texts and loss of others. Yet, taking all of this evidence together, the conclusion that a major shift had occurred in marriage finance seems inescapable.[16] Moreover, in Sung times dowries often included land or enough money to purchase land, something uncommon earlier.

For the rest of this paper I shall treat it as established that between the eighth and the eleventh centuries marriage finance among the elite shifted from one in which the groom's family bore the larger burden in laying the economic foundations of the marriage (through betrothal gifts used to prepare the dowry) to one in which the bride's family also made major contribu-


112

tions, equaling or outweighing the husband's family's. I shall now turn to examining the causes and consequences of this change in marriage finance.

Shifts in Marriage Finance and the T'ang-Sung Transition

It is by now widely recognized that Chinese society underwent major transformations between the T'ang and the Sung dynasties. In standard textbook presentations, these transformations include the expansion of the economy, the growth of cities, a decline in state control over the distribution of land, the replacement of the aristocracy with an examination-based elite, the growth of autocracy, the decline of Buddhism, the rise of neo-Confucianism, the development of popular forms of culture, the shift in the center of Chinese culture to the south, the appearance of localized lineages, and so on. In this context it is not surprising that forms of marriage finance might also change. But what were the specific connections? Did certain changes in Chinese society lead to a decline in demands for expensive betrothal gifts? Did the same or other changes foster dowry escalation? Can other social or cultural changes be attributed to the increased importance of dowry?

Dowry escalation brought about not merely a change in the timing or direction of marriage payments, but a more major shift in the system of transmitting property toward "diverging devolution," to use Goody's (1973, 1976) term. Dowry involves transmission of property outside the patrilineal descent group through women whose sons and daughters bear their fathers' surnames. By contrast, betrothal gifts used by the bride's family to prepare the dowry (i.e., indirect dowry) normally ended up back under the control of patrilineal descendants. That is, for one generation these funds belonged to the wife who married in, but as long as she had a son, whatever was left would go to her offspring (if it had not already been absorbed into family property). In no period of traditional China did daughters inherit like sons, though they could be residual heirs when they had no brothers (see also McCreery 1976 and Chen 1985). In the Sung, therefore, when the cost of the dowry became substantial and exceeded the value of the betrothal gifts, families began regularly transmitting a portion of their wealth outside the boundaries of their patrilineal descendants.

Questions about the shift toward larger dowries and diverging devolution can be phrased at either the individual or the societal level. That is, one can ask why men in the transition period chose to send their daughters with valuable dowries when they could probably still have married them without such expenditures. One can also ask why property holders as a class would transmit some of their property through daughters to grandsons of other surnames. The best explanation would probably make sense at both of these levels.

In modern China, dowry has generally been more lavish among the rich


113

than the poor, and so has been attributed to the status consciousness of the members of the wife-giving family who "do not wish to demean themselves before the other family" (Freedman 1979:258; see also Ahern 1974 and Watson 1981). Goody's (1976:99-114) comparative analysis also links diverging devolution to stratification, particularly the kind that comes in with plow-based agriculture. Linking dowry with status differentiation, however, provides no insight into the historical shift toward large dowries in China, as T'ang aristocratic society was if anything more concerned with status and prestige than the Sung elite. The T'ang case shows that the size of betrothal gifts (largely used for indirect dowry) could just as well serve as symbols of high status as direct dowry. Moreover, social and economic inequalities seem to have been just as well reproduced by this system of transmitting property.

The presence or absence of substantial dowry (that is, dowry in excess of the betrothal gifts) has also been linked to the need for affinal connections to people in distant localities (Watson 1981; Gallin and Gallin 1985). The logic here is that dowry makes marriage exchange unequal (the side that sent both the woman and the dowry clearly sent more), and as Mauss (1967) argued, unbalanced gifts keep relationships active. The possibility that affinal relations became more important in Sung times is discussed below.

A third explanation for the distribution of dowry payments stresses the role of commercialization (Harrell and Dickey 1985). Dowry is almost always displayed and its value readily interpreted by all concerned as a measure of the wealth of the bride's family. In more commercialized societies, determining status on the basis of wealth is common, as is competition for such status. Harrell and Dickey (1985) cite historical shifts where the introduction of dowry (generally in recent times) accompanied commercialization, sometimes spreading from town to country.

The kinds, timing, and value of marriage prestations also changed many times over the course of European history. Early imperial Roman families gave daughters dowries, the size of which slowly escalated. Then after about A.D. 200 the groom or his family started making premarital gifts to the bride (indirect dowry), which also followed an inflationary course, so that by the fifth century an emperor could denounce the avarice of parents with marriageable daughters. In the sixth century Justinian ruled that each family should make equal contributions. Herlihy associates these shifts with changes in the supply of potential mates caused by such things as female infanticide, the popularity of bachelorhood, changes in the age at marriage, and religions that promoted celibacy (1985:14-23; see also Saller 1984 and Dixon 1985 on the period to A.D. 200). In the Chinese case, it does not seem likely that changes in age at marriage or proportions marrying were large enough to affect the market for brides and grooms, so the Roman case is probably not a good model for comparison.

The Germanic peoples who invaded the Roman Empire in the fifth cen-


114

tury made gifts from the husband to the bride (somewhat analogous to the indirect dowry of Chinese betrothal gifts), and these also seem to have followed an inflationary course. Gradually, the contributions of the wives' families also seem to have grown (Hughes 1978:265-69, 272-73). In the eleventh century, dowry from the wife's family had reemerged in Italy, southern France, and Spain "in the wake of peace, economic and demographic growth, and the establishment of public authority" as well as land shortage and a "crisis in status" (ibid., 1978:276, 288). By the fourteenth century, especially in northern Italy, dowries had become extremely burdensome to bride-giving families at all social levels. Hughes suggests that dowry inflation was related to its use as a mechanism for alliance in a "status-conscious yet mobile world" (ibid., 288). The parallels to the Chinese case shall be explored below.

Hughes also argues that this dotal regime reflects a revision of property rights that restrengthened patrilineal principles: husbands did not want to assign rights to their property to wives, but natal families were willing to do so to daughters, on the understanding that the daughters could make no further claims on them (ibid., 287-88). In the Chinese case, dowry escalation may have been linked to emphasis on patrilineal principles, but my guess is that cause and effect worked the other way around: men wished to reassert patrilineal principles in part because they objected to the transfer of property through women. Goody (1983:257-59) interprets this late medieval shift from indirect to direct dowry mostly as one of timing. That is, instead of inheriting property at their parents' deaths, daughters were receiving it when they wed. As mentioned above, the Chinese case cannot be interpreted this way, for inheritance was not normally bilateral.

For the Chinese case, I think that transformations in the economy laid the groundwork for the shift toward diverging devolution, but that the real growth in dowries occurred first and most crucially in the elite. Economic changes included commercialization and freer forms of land tenure. In mid-T'ang the government largely gave up attempting to control the private ownership of land or its transfer from one generation to the next. The use of money also began a steady climb, with the government issuing twenty times as much money per year in the mid-eleventh century as it had at its height in the T'ang. People at all social levels thus had new opportunities to use property (money, land, or the goods that could be bought with money) to offer dowries that would strengthen affinal relations. As part of their strategies for advancement, especially in the political sphere, men in the elite took to providing their daughters with substantial dowries. The prominence of the dowries of the elite brought the concept of dowry fully into the repertoire of Chinese kinship practices. The custom of channeling wealth through dowries would then have spread to lower levels largely through a trickle-down effect as people regularly attempted to raise their own status by


115

copying the mores of those a step above them. From then on, although dowry became obligatory in the highest social level, it was optional at lower levels, and in Republican times at least was found among ordinary people in some parts of the country but not in others (Cohen 1976:164-91; Watson 1984; Chen 1985).

Because I think the escalation of dowry among the elite played a crucial role in its full admission to the repertoire of kinship practices and because there is so much more material on dowry among the elite, here I shall confine my analysis to the reasons elite men chose to send dowries with their daughters.

Social Structure and Dowry

Differences between T'ang and Sung social stratification are well known. The families that became established in the Northern Sung were rarely descendants of the leading T'ang families (even if some claimed such connections). Pedigree by itself was less of an asset in the Sung. The growing bureaucracy offered more opportunities for members of local elite families through the expanded examination system. The notion of an educated class of families whose members occasionally held office gained general recognition, displacing the T'ang notion of a super-elite of families whose members nearly all held office. Elite men were embedded in localized kinship groups, differing markedly from the dispersed kinship groups of the T'ang aristocratic families.[17]

The size of the educated class grew rapidly in Sung times, probably in large part because as the economy expanded, it could support more local landlords and wealthy merchants. As a consequence, the numbers of those competing for elite positions seem to have steadily outstripped the supply of valued places, at both the national and local levels. Thus the culture of the elite in Sung times was if anything more competitive than in T'ang. The basic rules of civil service recruitment were changed several times, and there was a persistent tendency for those with good connections to devise ways to favor people of their own kind (through "protection" privileges, "sponsorship," "facilitated," or "avoidance" examinations, and so on) (see Chaffee 1985:101-5; Umehara 1985:423-500; Chang Pang-wei 1986). Sung sources are full of complaints about the nepotism of those in high office. For instance, in 1041 Sun Mien charged that high officials would recommend or sponsor their affinal relatives (ch'in-ch'i ) (CP 132:5a). In 1165 an official protested that the advantageous "avoidance" examinations were being taken not merely by agnatic relatives but by cousins through father's sister and mother's brother (both fifth-rank mourning relatives) (SHY hsuan-chü 16:13a-b). Even more common was the complaint that "cold, solitary" (han-ku ) scholars had a hard time getting ahead. Men with high-ranking close agnatic


116

relatives were not "cold" or "solitary," but neither were those with good affinal connections. At the same time, the dangers of nepotism were recognized and efforts made to contain them, especially by prohibiting specified relatives from serving under or examining each other (see Niida 1942:287-302 and Chang Pang-wei 1986). These efforts to curb nepotism also served to advertise the range and depth of kin who could be of use.

Does the inflation of dowries have anything to do with the political and social changes that led to this transformation of class structure in the Sung? Large betrothal gifts apparently disappeared with the social groups that practiced them. In the T'ang, there is no evidence that such girls were common outside the circle of aristocratic families. But there is no reason that the disappearance of excessive betrothal gifts would have to lead to exaggerated dowries.

The tendency for dowry to escalate in the late Five Dynasties and Sung appears to be related to the ecological situation of the emerging elite. Officials and aspirants to office who needed connections in order to facilitate promotions through sponsorship, to gain allies in factional disputes, and so on had to build up networks. This could be done through nonkinship means, such as through the ties of teachers and students or officials and their subordinates. But kinship ties have advantages, for they can be extended much further, to brothers, sons, grandsons, and so on. The dislocations of the tenth century seem to have resulted in many men finding themselves cut off from both patrilineal and affinal kin. For instance, Shih Chieh (1005-45), in describing the history of his family, noted that the first ancestor to move to their current location 150 years earlier had found himself with neither brothers nor affinal kin (TLSHS shih-wen :251; see also Matsui 1968). In such cases it was easier to build up networks of affinal kin through marriages with families long settled in that place than to wait several generations for the family to grow into a sizable patrilineal descent group. This use of marriage to establish networks occurred at both the national and local levels. Robert Hartwell found that of 210 marriages involving the thirty-five most eminent "families" of the Northern Sung (960-1126), just over half (115) were to others in these families originally from other parts of the country (1982:423). Robert Hymes (1986) found that until the end of the Northern Sung when official families migrated to Fu-chou (Kiangsi), they quickly arranged marriages to the leading local families.

In the T'ang those with wealth could not change the key element in their social status except by fraud: their home prefecture (choronym) and family name were fixed. A family hoping to convert wealth into social status could perhaps facilitate ties to these prestigious families by offering betrothal gifts or dowries verging on bribes. But the marriages contracted could only be expected to change the general evaluation of the family's status very slowly, after at least a couple of generations. In the Sung, starting with very little of


117

an established elite, family name per se meant little, so there was more to be gained by "buying" marriage connections.

Granting that there may have been more men eager to convert wealth into status in the early Sung, why did they use this wealth for dowries rather than betrothal gifts? Here I will argue that dowry offered three advantages over betrothal gifts: it made a better 'bribe"; it provided more flexibility for family strategies; and it made affinal ties stronger.

Dowry was a superior bait because betrothal gifts were supposed to be returned as dowry. By insisting on valuable betrothal gifts when marrying out a daughter, one may have guaranteed that she would have an adequate dowry, but one was not improving the financial health of one's own patriline. Dowry, by contrast, involved transfer from one patriline to another. Although the groom's father, who arranged the marriage, was not to have any control over the dowry, and even his son was supposed to gain his wife's consent on its use, it would eventually go to his son's sons and daughters (see CMC 5:140; MCC 33:31a-b, 33:34b-37a; Ebrey 1984b:101-20). Its final destination would not be trivial to a man worried about the eventual division of the family property among several sons. Mercantile families could use handsome dowries to marry their daughters into families of officials.[18] Epitaphs for the early Sung also show rich official families marrying their daughters to promising young men, giving them large dowries.[19] They did this in part to avoid marrying down or losing prestige, but also because even well-established families could benefit from connections to such men. And the groom also had much to gain. Ssu-ma Kuang criticized the practice of choosing brides on the basis of transient wealth and rank. "How could a man of spirit retain his pride if he got rich by using his wife's assets or gained high station by relying on her influence?" (SMSSI 3:29). Probably many young men would forgo some pride toward those ends.

My second argument is that dowry increased the options available in advancement strategies. Transmission of property along the patrilineal line through division among sons was inflexible: all brothers' shares were to be the same. Dowry allowed, to some extent at least, a differentiation among brothers inasmuch as dowries for each incoming bride were separately negotiated. Thus, a family with several sons and daughters could make different decisions for each one. Sometimes they could concentrate on affirming their prestige by arranging the best matches, ignoring how much dowry their sons' brides would bring and using up much of their disposable income for the daughters' dowries. Alternatively, they could worry about the future estates of their sons after division and try to soften the consequences by seeking sons-in-law who would take their daughters without large dowries or daughters-in-law for their sons who would come with good dowries. Another strategy might be to have one or more sons wait until he passed the examinations before arranging his marriage in the hope of securing a better dowry for


118

him. Of course, dowry would never be the sole consideration in marriage negotiations; a well-connected father-in-law could be worth more than an ample dowry. Moreover, a family might consider it wiser to invest more in education and less in marriages.[20]

My third argument is that the obligations inherent in an affinal relationship could be strengthened by a large dowry. In an article published in 1981, I showed that the provision of dowry to daughters was associated with continuing obligations between the families of the bride and the groom (Ebrey 1981:124). The parents of the bride could expect more from their daughter, her husband, and her sons when they had married her out with a respectable dowry. The direct evidence I cited included Yuan Ts'ai's advice to families with ample property to give their daughters a share of it on the grounds that their sons might prove incapable and they might therefore have to depend on their daughters' families even for their funerals and ancestral sacrifices (Ebrey 1984b:224). I also pointed to strong ties between daughters and their natal families, ranging from daughters who took in their widowed mothers or arranged their parents' funerals or cared for their orphaned younger brothers, to parents or brothers who took responsibility for their widowed daughters or sisters.

One can easily posit (as Yuan Ts'ai did) that a woman who had received material assets from her parents had a greater obligation to aid them if they were ever in need than a woman who had not. One can also suppose that a widow with a dowry at her disposal (who either had no children or who was taking them with her) could more easily choose where she wished to live than one without much of a dowry. There is no obvious reason, however, for a family that had sent off a daughter with a substantial dowry to feel more obligated to take her back than one that had provided little if anything beyond recycling of the betrothal gifts. In these cases, the logic of unbalanced exchanges might be what kept these ties active. I also suspect that dowry strengthened affinal ties because it created lingering claims to common property. Just as brothers were bound to each other as coparceners of graveyards and ancestral halls even after division of the household, affinal relatives were linked through mutual interest in the disposition of the dowry and this kept their ties alive.[21]

Another way to bring out the relationship between dowry and continuing reciprocal obligations is to consider either end of the spectrum of marriage finance. Families who sold their daughter as a concubine provided no dowry but received large "betrothal gifts" of cash. It was generally understood that they were losing kinship rights over her, that they might never meet their grandchildren, that these grandchildren need not come to their funeral, and so on (Ebrey 1986a and Watson, this volume). At the other extreme were uxorilocal arrangements whereby families took in husbands for their daughters, generally expecting little or nothing in the way of betrothal gifts but


119

TABLE 3.1
Matrilateral and Affinal Relatives to Be Avoided by Officials

Woman
Relative

Mourning
Grade
a


Relatives to Be Avoided

Mother

2a

her father, grandfather (FF), great-grandfather (FFF), father's brother, brother, cousin (FBS), nephew (BS and ZS), brother-in-law (ZH), and sister's daughter's husband

Wife

2b

same as motherb

Grandmother (FM)

2c

none

Uncle's wife (FBW)

2c

none

Daughter

2c

her husband, sons, husband's father and brother, daughter's husband

Aunt (FZ)

3

her husband

Sister

3

her husband and son

Son's wife

3

her father and brother

Nephew's wife (BSW)

3

none

Niece (BD)

3

none

Cousin (FBD)

4

none

Brother's wife

4

none

Granddaughter (SD)

4

her husband

Nephew's daughter (BSD)

5

none

SOURCE : SHY chih-kuan 63:4.

NOTE : For simplicity's sake, this table is limited to cases where the man might plausibly have lived sometime in a common household with the woman who provided the link.

a The mourning grades for female agnates are those they assumed upon marriage. These grades are based on CL 4:10b-15a.

b Not given in SHY , but probably a scribal error because in all the other lists, mother's and wife's natal relatives are given together (e.g., CYTFSL 8:101).

providing their daughter with a dowry of much or all of their property. Such sons-in-law had many obligations to their wives' families—to support them, bury them, and see to it that their sacrifices continued.

Among the elite, strong affinal ties could be used not merely for kinship purposes (care of widows and orphans) but also for political ones. As anecdotes attest, families of officials seem to have often thought they could recruit sons-in-law with better career prospects by offering better dowries. The goal of such efforts does not seem so much to have been prestige but connections: sons-in-law make good clients and political allies. This line of thinking is clearly reflected in Sung rules on nepotism. Table 3.1 lists affinal and matrilateral relatives under whom a man could not serve according to the nepotism rules of 1070. It is organized according to the woman who served as the kinship link between the two men.


120

As can easily be seen, the gradation in the scope of relatives to be avoided does not correspond to mourning grades. In Chinese kinship reckoning, a man is considered closely related to his father's brother and he mourns this uncle's wife at grade two. Yet his ties of obligation to this woman's natal family were not considered strong enough to make avoidance necessary in a bureaucratic setting. The same is true of the families of the wives of a man's brothers and nephews. Even in the case of the family into which his sister had married, only her husband and son had to be avoided, not, for instance, her husband's father or brother. A man was considered most likely to feel obligations to men in his mother's and wife's families, and then to a lesser extent, to those in the families of his daughter's husband and son's wife.

The logic here, I contend, is that of dowry and not of consanguinity. It is true that a man is related by blood to his mother's family, but he is also tied by blood to his father's mother's family, to his father's sister's family, and so on. Moreover, he is not related by blood to anyone in his wife's family. A fairly large number of people in the family that sent a girl and a dowry had to be avoided by her husband and sons, but other members of the family into which she married are generally not involved. (That is, one had to avoid serving in the same office with a first cousin of one's wife, but not with the brother or father of one's brother's wife.) The difference would seem to be that one received nothing from the dowry a brother's wife brought, but brothers, grandparents, and uncles of one's wife could all have been coparceners of the family that sent her dowry. Moreover, one was the foremost contributor to the dowry of a daughter, somewhat less to that of a sister and son's daughter, and much less to that of a brother's daughter, and so on.

Let me reorganize my argument to sort out the causal chain that includes the shift toward large dowries. I see the growth of the economy, increasing availability of money, and freer transfer of land as general preconditions for both the growth of the educated class and the greater transfer of wealth through dowry. I see the political situation of the tenth century as bringing to the fore people who had no pedigree but who had been able to build armies or staff bureaucracies through various personal connections. Whenever such connections are useful, affinal ties will gain importance. Dowry, I argue, was an especially good way for those with wealth to try to secure preferred affinal relations (because it made a better bait, allowed flexible family strategies, and strengthened the ties once they were arranged). Given the competitiveness with which Sung men pursued positions in the elite, it became difficult for families to gain a useful connection through a daughter without providing a dowry. In time, through market forces, it became nearly impossible to find any sort of suitable family for her. The civil service recruitment system was, meanwhile, evolving. The usefulness of affinal connections was continually confirmed and reproduced in this arena, both through the extension of privileges of facilitated entry into office to a wide range of kin


121

and through provisions made to cut these privileges back. By the time nepotism rules were compiled in the mid-Sung, the transfer of dowry was clearly associated with the assumed flow of favors. There is no point in asking which came first: dowry as a means to transfer property; an elite that continually used affinal kinship to create and repair networks that would secure or advance one in local or national politics; or a civil service system that continuously struggled against and gave ground to the desire of those inside and outside the system to use personal connections for both entry and advancement. These three phenomena were systematically related to each other and each kept the others strong.

Conclusion

By way of conclusion, I would like to consider briefly the implications that my interpretation of the shifts in marriage finance from the T'ang to the Sung may have for some established ideas about marriage payments and social structure.

First I would like to consider Goody's (1976) suggestion that dowry is associated with exclusive marriage practices and tends to preserve economic inequalities, as dowered marriages are arranged predominantly among families with comparable wealth. From the Chinese case, one could argue that indirect dowry serves this purpose better than direct dowry. In the T'ang it was easy for the wealth of the aristocracy to stay within the aristocracy because a family's property seldom had to leave the patriline except for the journey of betrothal gifts to the homes of future brides where it was turned into dowries and then returned, to again become regular family property after a generation. If the families of the brides neither retained any of the gifts nor supplemented them (each of which happened some of the time), then all family property would eventually devolve to patrilineal descendants.

In the Sung substantial dowries regularly channeled property into other patrilines. At the same time, it is much harder to identify a circle that kept property within its own boundaries. The size of the educated class steadily expanded during the Sung, and new chin-shih seem to have been able to obtain dowries and therefore wealth from either rich families with no prior official connections or the families of officials. In the Chinese case, thus, betrothal gifts (bridewealth to be returned as indirect dowry) went along with a more constricted elite that passed down its standing and probably its wealth to its patrilineal descendants, and dowry was most visibly used by an expanding elite that was absorbing new families at both the local and national levels.

The second general issue I wish to raise concerns dowry and patrilineality. Bridewealth is much more common than dowry in African societies organized into segmentary patrilineages. Dowry is much more common in


122

societies with bilateral inheritance and other bilateral tendencies (such as Europe). The civilizations of Asia fit between these two poles, dowry often coexisting with strong patrilineal kinship organization. Is there thus any generalizable relationship between marriage finance and forms of kinship organization? Will shifts in one have anything to do with shifts in the other?

In the Chinese case, new forms of localized patrilineages began to appear in several parts of the country in late Sung (Ebrey 1986b). These local lineages brought together agnatic relatives related through a common ancestor many generations back for joint ancestral rites. Groups of agnates frequently erected halls for these rites, set aside land to pay for them, and compiled genealogies. In many areas they became major forces in local politics. Chronologically, the shift toward substantial dowries was visible before such descent groups appeared. Could diverging devolution have somehow triggered the growth of lineages? Or could they both be manifestations of some larger change in Chinese kinship organization?

I would argue, from what evidence there is, that these began as independent developments, substantial dowries taking off first among the elite, localized lineages gaining strength among ordinary people, though in time each reached to all social levels and each shaped the other's development. Large dowries had a couple of hundred years to get well established before descent groups were significant, though later the form and distribution of dowries were shaped by a context that included descent groups. Descent groups in China developed in an environment in which the elite and often commoners transmitted some wealth through dowries.

The spread of dowry may even be thought to have had a small role in shaping the form descent groups took in China. I see a connection between the prevalence of substantial dowry and the call for a strengthening of patrilineal principles. Some Sung neo-Confucians recognized that the shift toward transmitting property through daughters was a threat to China's traditional patrilineal, patriarchal family system. Their call for a "revival of the descent line system (tsung )" was motivated in part by their objections to the strength of affinal relations and their fears concerning the breakup of patrimonies. This descent line rhetoric, in turn, helped to shape the way Chinese descent groups and lineages were eventually conceived (Ebrey 1984a; 1986b).

Descent line rhetoric and the growth of descent groups can also be given some credit for curbing the trend toward dowry. In Yuan (1215-1368) and Ming (1368-1644) times legal restrictions were placed on married women's control of their dowries, in particular their right to take them with them if they were widowed or divorced (YTC hu-pu, hun-yin :816-17; Tai 1978:105). As Jennifer Holmgren argues, these restrictions probably had much to do with problems relating to Mongol family practices, such as the levirate (1986). Yet the political success of Ch'eng-Chu neo-Confucianism also facilitated this revision of the law. Descent groups, where they existed, may also


123

have limited the incentive for large dowries among ordinary people by providing them with an adequate set of social connections. In recent times, dowry among ordinary farmers seems to have been larger in areas without strong lineages. Where there were strong lineages, the rich gave dowries, but not the ordinary poor farmer.

By ending this essay with a discussion of how the escalation of dowries was curbed, I wish to underline the dynamic nature of the changes I have described here. The growth of dowries can be seen as an effect of economic and political changes, but it also had effects of its own. It generated not only compatible institutions (such as legal elaborations) and symbols (associations with prestige) but also opposing forces (in rhetoric, law, and descent groups). These conflicting effects also interacted through time in complex ways, obscuring simple functional relations in the flux of social life.

Glossary

Chang Yao-tso inline image

Chao-chün Li inline image

Ch'en inline image

Cheng inline image

Ch'eng Lin inline image

chia-chuanginline image

chia-shihinline image

chia-tsuinline image

Chiang Pao inline image

ch'in-ch'iinline image

Ch'ing-ho Ts'ui inline image

Chu Yü inline image

chüaninline image

chuang-lieninline image

chunginline image

Fan-yang Lu inline image

Feng Ching inline image

Fu Pi inline image

han-kuinline image

Hou K'o inline image

hsi-t'iehinline image

huinline image

hu-chuehinline image

Hu Ying inline image

hun-shuinline image

Kao-tsung inline image

Li inline image

Li Hua inline image

Li Ti inline image

lieninline image

lien-chüinline image

lien-chü chuanginline image

Liu K'o-chuanginline image

Liu Tsai inline image

Lung-hsi Li inline image

men-huinline image

men-tiinline image

na-chenginline image

na-piinline image

p'in-liinline image

p'in-ts'aiinline image

Po Chü-i inline image

Po-ling Ts'ui inline image

Shen Yueh inline image

Shih Chieh inline image

shih-ta-fuinline image

soinline image

Ssu-ma Kuang inline image

ssu-ts'aiinline image

Sun Chuehinline image

Sun Mieninline image

ta-fuinline image

T'ai-tsung inline image

T'ai-yuan Wang inline image

ti-yininline image

Ting Chih inline image

ting-t'iehinline image

ts'ai-ch'aninline image

Ts'ai Hsiang inline image

ts'ao-t'iehinline image

Tseng Puinline image

tsu-tsunginline image

Ts'uiinline image

Ts'ui Piao inline image

tsunginline image

tzu-chuanginline image

tzu-sunginline image

Wang T'ung inline image

Wang Yuan inline image

Weng Fu inline image

Yang Su inline image

Yen Chih-t'ui inline image

Ying-yang Cheng inline image

Yuan Ts'ai inline image


127

References

Primary Sources

CCC Chieh-chai chiinline image, by Yuan Hsieh inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

CCCC Hsin-pien shih-wen lei-yao ch'i-cha ch'ing-ch'ieninline image. Photo reprint of 1324 edition.

CKCY Chen-kuan chen-yaoinline image, by Wu Ching inline image. Shanghai: Ku-chi ch'u-pan-she, 1978.

CL Chu-tzu chia liinline image, by Chu Hsi inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu edition.

CLC Ch'en Liang chiinline image, by Ch'en Liang inline image. Taipei: Ho-lo t'u-shu ch'u-pan-she, 1976.

CLP Chi-le pieninline image, by Chuang Ch'o inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

CMC Ming-kung shu-p'an ch'ing-ming chiinline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1987.

CP Hsu tzu-chih t'ung-chien ch'ang-pieninline image, Li T'ao inline image. Reprint. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü.

CPTSHS Ching-pen t'ung-su hsiao-shuoinline image. Shanghai: Chung-kuo ku-tien wen-hsueh ch'u-pan-she, 1954.

CS Chung-shuoinline image, by Wang T'ung inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

CTW Ch'üan T'ang weninline image, ed. Tung Kao inline image et al. Taipei: Ching-wei reprint of 1814 edition.

CWKWC Chu Wen-kung wen-chiinline image, by Chu Hsi inline image. Taipei: Han-ching reprint of Po-na edition.

CWTS Chiu Wu-tai shihinline image, by Hsueh Chü-cheng inline image and Hsu Wu-tang inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1976.

CYIL Chien-yen i-lai hsi-nien yao luinline image, by Li Hsin-ch'uan inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

CYTFSL Ch'ing-yuan t'iao-fa shih-leiinline image, by Hsieh Shen-fu inline image. Tokyo: Koten kenkyukai reprint of Sung edition.

ECC Erh-Ch'eng chiinline image, by Ch'eng Hao inline image and Ch'eng I inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1981.

HLPY Hsin-pien hun-li pei-yung yueh-lao hsin-shuinline image. National Central Library. Microfilm, Sung edition.

HMTC Shih-wen lei-chü han-mo ta-ch'üaninline image, by Liu Ying-li inline image. 1307 edition.

HNHS Ho-nan hsien-sheng wen-chiinline image, by Yin Chu inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

HTHS Hou-ts'un hsien-sheng ta ch'üan chiinline image, by Liu K'o-chuang inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

HTS Hsin T'ang shuinline image, by Ou-yang Hsiu inline image and Sung Ch'i inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1975.

ICC I-chien chihinline image, by Hung Mai inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1981.

KKC Kung-k'uei chiinline image, by Lou Yueh inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

KSC Kung-shih chiinline image, by Liu Ch'ang inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

LCC Le-ching chiinline image, by Li Chao-ch'i inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu edition.


128

LTLWC Lü Tung-lai wen-chiinline image, by Lü Tsu-ch'ien inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

MCC Mien-chai chiinline image, by Huang Kan inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu edition.

MLL Meng liang luinline image, by Wu Tzu-mu inline image. In Tung-ching meng-hua lu wai ssu-chung .

MTC Man-t'ang chiinline image, by Liu Tsai inline image. Chia-yeh t'ang ts'ung-shu edition.

NCCIK Nan-chien chia-i kaoinline image, by Han Yuan-chi inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

OYHCC Ou-yang Hsiu ch'üan-chiinline image, by Ou-yang Hsiu inline image. Taipei: Chung-kuo wen-hsueh ming-chu chi edition, Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1971.

PCC P'eng-ch'eng chiinline image, by Liu Pin inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

PCKT P'ing-chou k'o-t'aninline image, by Chu Yü inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

PCS Pei Ch'i shuinline image, by Li Te-lin inline image and Li Po-yao inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1972.

PCTCC Pei-ch'i ta ch'üan chiinline image by Ch'en Ch'un inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu edition.

PCWC P'an-chou wen-chiinline image, by Hung Kua inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

PSHC Pei-shan hsiao-chiinline image, by Ch'eng Chü inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

SHT Sung hsing t'unginline image, by Tou I inline image. 1918; reprint, Taipei: Wen-hai, 1974.

SHY Sung hui-yao chi-peninline image, ed. Hsu Sung inline image et al. Reprint. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1964.

SLKC (Hsin-pien tsuan t'u tseng-lei ch'ün-shu lei-yao) shih-lin kuang-chiinline image, by Ch'en Yuan-ching inline image. Naikaku bunko Yuan edition.

SMSSI Ssu-ma shih shu-iinline image, by Ssu-ma Kuang inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

SS Sung shihinline image, ed. T'o T'o inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1977.

SSWCL Shao-shih wen-chien luinline image, by Shao Po-wen inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1983.

STPC Su Tung-p'o chiinline image, by Su Shih inline image. Kuo-hsueh chi-pen ts'ung-shu edition.

STJC Shui-tung jih-chiinline image, by Yeh Sheng inline image. Pai-pu ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

SuiS Sui shuinline image, by Wei Cheng inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1973.

SWC Sung wen chieninline image, by Lü Tsu-ch'ien inline image. Kuo-hsueh chi-pen ts'ung-shu edition.

TCMHL Tung-ching meng-hua lu (wai ssu-chung)inline image, by Meng Yuan-lao inline image. Shanghai: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1962.

THY T'ang hui-yaoinline image, by Wang P'u inline image. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü edition.

TLSHS Ts'u-lai Shih hsien-sheng wen-chiinline image, by Shih Chieh inline image .


129

Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1984.

TLSI T'ang lü shu-iinline image, by Ch'ang-sun Wu-chi inline image et al. Kuo-ksueh chi-pen ts'ung-shu edition.

TPKC T'ai-p'ing kuang-chiinline image, ed. Li Fang inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1961.

TYL T'ang yü lininline image, by Wang Tang inline image. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1967.

WH Wen-hsuaninline image, ed. Hsiao T'ung inline image. Kuo-hsueh chi-pen ts'ung-shu edition.

WLCC Wang Lin-ch'uan ch'üan chiinline image, by Wang An-shih inline image. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1966.

YLMC Yun-lu man-ch'aoinline image, by Chao Yen-wei inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

YSC Yeh Shih chiinline image, by Yeh Shih inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1961.

YSCH Yen-shih chia-hsun chi-chiehinline image, by Yen Chih-t'ui inline image. Taipei: Wen-ming shu-chü, 1982.

YTC Ta Yuan sheng-cheng kuo-ch'ao tien-changinline image. Facsimile reprint of Yuan edition.

Secondary Works

Ahern, Emily M. 1974. "Affines and the Rituals of Kinship." In Religion and Ritual in Chinese Society , ed. Arthur P. Wolf. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Burns, Ian Robert. 1973. "Private Law in Traditional China (Sung Dynasty)." Ph.D. diss., Oxford University.

Chaffee, John W. 1985. The Thorny Gates of Learning: A Social History of Examinations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Chang Hsiu-jung inline image. 1976. T'ang-tai wen-hsueh so piao-hsien chih hun-su yen-chiuinline image (A study of marriage customs revealed in T'ang literature). M.A. thesis, National Cheng-chi University, Taipei.

Chang Pang-wei inline image. 1986. "Sung-tai pi-ch'in pi-chi chih-tu shu-p'ing" inline image (An account of the Sung system of avoiding relatives). Ssu-ch'uan Shih-ta hsueh-pao 1:16-23.

Chao Shou-yen inline image. 1963. "T'ang-tai hun-yin li-su k'ao-lueh" inline image (A brief study of wedding customs in the T'ang period). Wen-shih 3:185-95.

Chen, Chung-min. 1985. "Dowry and Inheritance." In The Chinese Family and Its Ritual Behavior , ed. Hsieh Jih-chang and Chuang Ying-chang. Taipei: Academia Sinica, Institute of Ethnology.

Ch'en Ku-yuan inline image. 1936; reprint, 1978. Chung-kuo hun-yin shihinline image (A history of marriage in China). Taipei: Commercial Press.

Cohen, Myron L. 1976. House United, House Divided: The Chinese Family in Taiwan . New York: Columbia University Press.

Ch'ü, T'ung-tsu. 1965. Law and Society in Traditional China . Paris: Mouton.

Comaroff, J. L. 1980. "Introduction." In The Meaning of Marriage Payments , ed. J. L. Comaroff. New York: Academic Press.

Davis, Richard L. 1986. Court and Family in Sung China, 960-1279: Bureaucratic Success and Kinship Fortunes for the Shih of Ming-chou . Durham: Duke University Press.


130

Dixon, Suzanne. 1985. "The Marriage Alliance in the Roman Elite." Journal of Family History 10.4:353-78.

Dull, Jack L. 1978. "Marriage and Divorce in Han China: A Glimpse at 'Pre-Confucian' Society." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Ebrey, Patricia Buckley. 1978. The Aristocratic Families of Early Imperial China: A Case Study of the Po-ling Ts'ui Family . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1981. "Women in the Kinship System of the Southern Song Upper Class." Historical Reflections 8: l 13-28.

———. 1984a. "Conceptions of the Family in the Sung Dynasty." Journal of Asian Studies 43.2:219-45.

———. 1984b. Family and Property in Sung China: Yüan Ts'ai's Precepts for Social Life . Princeton: Princeton University Press.

———. 1985. "T'ang Guides to Verbal Etiquette." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 45:581-613.

———. 1986a. "Concubines in Sung China." Journal of Family History 11:1-24.

———. 1986b. "Early Stages in the Development of Descent Groups." In Kinship Organization in Late Imperial China, 1000-1940 , ed. Patricia Buckley Ebrey and James L. Watson. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

———. 1988. "The Dynamics of Elite Domination in Sung China." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 48:493-519.

Fang Chien-hsin inline image. 1986. "Sung-tai hun-yin lun-ts'ai" inline image Discussing wealth in Sung period marriages). Li-shih yen-chiuinline image, no. 3:178-90.

Freedman, Maurice. 1979. "Rites and Duties, or Chinese Marriage." In The Study of Chinese Society , ed. G. William Skinner. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Gallin, Bernard, and Rita S. Gallin. 1985. "Matrilateral and affinal Relationships in Changing Chinese Society." In The Chinese Family and Its Ritual Behavior , ed. Hsieh Jih-chang and Chuang Ying-chang. Taipei: Academia Sinica, Institute of Ethnology.

Goody, Jack. 1973. "Bridewealth and Dowry in Africa and Eurasia." In Bridewealth and Dowry , by Jack Goody and S.J. Tambiah. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1976. Production and Reproduction: A Comparative Study of the Domestic Domain . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Harrell, Stevan. 1987. "Marriage, Mortality, and the Developmental Cycle in Chinese Lineages." Paper presented at the Conference on Chinese Lineage Demography.

Harrell, Stevan, and Sara A. Dickey. 1985. "Dowry Systems in Complex Societies." Ethnology 24.2:105-20.

Hartwell, Robert M. 1982. "Demographic, Political, and Social Transformation of China, 750-1550." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 42:365-442.

Herlihy, David. 1985. Medieval Households . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Holmgren, Jennifer. 1985. "The Economic Foundations of Virtue: Widow-Remarriage in Early and Modern China." Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs 13:1-27.


131

———. 1986. "Observations on Marriage and Inheritance Practices in Early Mongol and Yüan Society, with Particular Reference to the Levirate." Journal of Asian History 20:127-92.

Hughes, Diane Owen. 1978. "From Brideprice to Dowry in Mediterranean Europe." Journal of Family History 3.3:262-96.

Hymes, Robert P. 1986. Statesmen and Gentlemen: The Elite of Fu-chou, Chiang-hsi, in Northern and Southern Sung . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Johnson, David G. 1977a. "The Last Years of a Great Clan: The Li Family of Chao Chün in Late T'ang and Early Sung." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 37:5-102.

———. 1977b. The Medieval Chinese Oligarchy . Boulder: Westview Press.

Lee, Thomas H. C. 1985. Government Education and Examinations in Sung China . Hong Kong: Chinese University Press.

Legge, James, trans. 1885; reprint, 1967. Li Chi, Book of Rites . New York: University Books.

Lü Ch'eng-chih inline image. 1935. Chung-kuo hun-yin chih-tu hsiao-shihinline image (A short history of marriage institutions in China). Rev. ed. Shanghai: Lung-hu shu-chü.

Ma Chih-su inline image. 1981. Chung-kuo ti hun-suinline image (Chinese marriage customs). Taipei: Ching-shih shu-chü.

McCreery, John L. 1976. "Women's Property Rights and Dowry in China and South Asia." Ethnology 15:163-74.

Macfarlane, Alan. 1986. Marriage and Love in England: Modes of Reproduction 1300-1840 . Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Matsui Shuichi inline image. 1968· "Hoku Sô shoki kanryô no ichi tenkei—Seki Kai to sono keifu o chûshin ni" inline image (A model of the early Northern Sung official, concentrating on Shih Chieh and his ancestry). Toyo gakuho 51.1:44-92.

Mauss, Marcel. 1925; reprint, 1966. The Gift: Forms and Functions of Exchange in Archaic Societies . New York: W. W. Norton.

Niida Noboru inline image. 1942. Shina mibunhôshiinline image (A history of status law in China). Tokyo: Zayuho kankokai.

Niu Chih-p'ing inline image. 1987. "T'ang-tai hun-yin ti k'ai-fang feng-ch'i" inline image (The liberated style of marriage in the T'ang period). Li-shih yen-chiu , no. 4:80-88.

Saller, Richard P. 1984. "Roman Dowry and the Devolution of Property in the Principate." Classical Quarterly 34:195-205.

Steele, John, trans. 1917. The I-li of Book of Etiquette and Ceremonial . 2 vols. London: Probsthain.

Tai, Yen-hui. 1978. "Divorce in Traditional Chinese Law." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

T'ao, Hsi-sheng inline image. 1966. Hun-yin yü chia-tsuinline image (Marriage and family). Taipei: Jen-jen wen-k'u edition.

Twitchett, Denis. 1960. "Documents on Clan Administration I: The Rules of Administration of the Charitable Estate of the Fan Clan." Asia Major , ser. 3, 8:1-35.

———. 1973. "The Composition of the T'ang Ruling Class: New Evidence from Tunhuang." Perspectives on the T'ang , ed. Arthur F. Wright and Denis Twitchett.


132

New Haven: Yale University Press.

Umehara Kaoru inline image. 1985. Sodai kanryoseido kenkyuinline image (Studies of the Sung bureaucratic system). Kyoto: Doho.

Watson, Rubie S. 1981. "Class Differences and Affinal Relations in South China." Man 16:593-615.

———. 1984. "Women's Property in Republican China: Rights and Practice." Republican China 10.1a:1-12.

Wong, Sun-ming. 1979. "Confucian Ideal and Reality: Transformation of the Institution of Marriage in T'ang China (A.D. 618-907)." Ph.D. diss., University of Washington.

Yang, Hsien-yi, and Gladys Yang, trans. 1957. The Courtesan's Jewel Box: Chinese Stories of the Xth-XVIIth Centuries . Peking: Foreign Languages Press.

Yang Shu-ta inline image. 1933; reprint, 1976. Han-tai hun-sang li-su k'aoinline image (An investigation of marriage and funerary customs in the Han period). Taipei: Hua-shih ch'u-pan-she.


133

Four
The Marriage of Sung Imperial Clanswomen

John W. Chaffee

The marriage connections of the Sung imperial clan might seem at first glance to be of questionable significance to the issue of marriage and inequality in China. Marriage of imperial clansmen and clanswomen did not affect succession to the throne or the creation of powerful consort families, like the imperial marriages studied by Jennifer Holmgren and Evelyn Rawski elsewhere in this volume. The imperial clan, in the Sung and other dynasties, was the closest the Chinese imperial system came to an hereditary aristocracy. Yet the clan might also be seen as a parasitic appendage of emperorship, an aristocracy without power because, in Northern Sung times at least, its members were barred from substantive, high-ranking political posts. Why, then, study the marriage relations of a group that was so obviously unique in Sung elite culture as the Chao clan?

The first and most obvious reason is that, like the medieval French royalty so brilliantly evoked by Georges Duby (1978), the Chaos were exemplary. Marriages of Chao princes and princesses were lavish affairs witnessed by the multitudes of the court and capital and enacted in accordance with detailed ritual codes (see also Rawski, in this volume). Even the weddings of distant kinsmen were public events given the prestige and the exchange of assets that accompanied them. Even if, as Holmgren argues in her chapter, imperial marriages reflected imperial needs more than the social practices of the elite, these marriages had great symbolic importance in the society at large. The second reason is that the Chaos were socially, politically, and economically powerful, though that power changed over time. Through most of the Northern Sung, they were excluded from political office and socially segregated within their palaces; but they were often influential with their kinsman, the emperor. In the Southern Sung, by contrast, the personal in-


134

fluence of the Chaos declined even as they came to fill local government posts in great numbers and produced two chief councillors.

The third reason is that marriage wove the Chaos into the fabric of Sung upper-class society. This paper will examine who, how, and where they married, but its particular focus will be the marriage of women out of the imperial clan. Because such marriages were a priori downward, or hypogamous (clanswomen were "sent down" [chiang ] out of the clan in contrast to women being "selected" [hsuan ] into the clan as wives), a built-in tension existed between an imperial clanswoman's status superiority and her gender inferiority. The problem of the highborn wife was common throughout Chinese history; what is of interest here is that it was commonly acknowledged and discussed for Sung clanswomen.

Finally, the Chao clan's marriage relations are of interest because of the abundant sources on them. Because the clan was an imperial, and not simply a private, concern, its marriage policy was the subject of a wealth of memorials, essays, edicts, and regulations. Most important are the seven chüan devoted to clan affairs and institutions in the Sung hui-yao .[1] The dynastic Sung History , Sung encyclopedias, memorial collections, and collected writings contain pertinent information too. The dynastic records of imperial princesses—daughters of emperors—together with the fourteen funerary inscriptions that I found for clanswomen (plus two other cases in which ample evidence of the marriage partners is available from other sources) do not begin to compare with those for clansmen.[2] The records are useful, however, as a biographical base for characterizing their marriages.

Using these sources in this essay, I shall attempt to piece together a picture of clanswomen's marriages, and changes in them, during the Sung. In doing so, I address three related questions. First, what kinds of exchanges were involved in the women's marriages and, more specifically, what were the purposes behind the government's clan marriage regulations? We shall see that an imposing array of goods and recruitment privileges constituted the official dowry of the clanswoman. Indeed, the inability of the groom's family to reciprocate in kind raises questions about the meaning of such marriage exchanges. Second, whom did the clanswomen marry? Drawing from both the imperial marriage regulations and inscription evidence, I shall show that the social and geographic backgrounds of the marriage partners varied both over time and according to the position of the woman within the clan. Third, how did these marriages deal with issues of inequality in light of the innate tension between the subordinate role clanswomen were supposed to assume in their husbands' families on the one hand, and the superior connections, resources, and power that they brought into their marriages on the other? Perhaps most important, we shall see how the same regulations and practices assumed very different meanings as the clan itself underwent radical


135

changes. For that reason, we must first consider, if only briefly, the history, structure, and character of the imperial clan itself.

The Imperial Clan

To begin on a semantic note, I am using the term "imperial clan" for the Chinese tsung-shih because by the Southern Sung it did in fact approximate the anthropologist's "clan"—that is, "a unilineal descent group of widest extent, in which the most inclusive relationships are not reckoned through a genealogy" (Goody 1983:295).[3] A caveat is necessary because the clan had what it called the Office of the Jade Register (Yü-tieh-so ), which maintained a comprehensive genealogy (SS 117:3890). By the thirteenth century, however, when thousands of clansmen were scattered around the empire and frequently related to each other only to the twelfth or thirteenth degree, the House of Chao acted far more like a clan than a lineage. This was especially true because the dynastic flight south at the end of the Northern Sung re-suited in a loss of genealogical records that exhaustive efforts at reconstruction could not fully remedy.

At the beginning of the Sung, the House of Chao consisted of the Chao brothers K'uang-yin (929-76), Chiung (939-97), and T'ing-mei (respectively the emperors T'ai-tsu [r. 960-76] and T'ai-tsung [r. 976-97] and the prince of Wei) and their families,[4] and it seems to have functioned with a minimum of organization. By the middle of the eleventh century, however, the Chaos' numbers and residences had proliferated, and they had their own bureaucracy, staffed at first by clansmen, which issued increasingly detailed regulations for the clan.[5] This organization was necessary because of the clan's spectacular growth during the Northern Sung. A twelfth-century enumeration, by generation and branch, of the clan's genealogy is shown in table 4.1. There are problems with interpreting the figures for the later generations on the list, for they were still being produced at the time of its compilation. Record keeping was also disrupted by the Jurchens' capture of much of the clan during the 1126 invasion. For the earlier generations, however, we can see a truly remarkable record of growth. The twenty-three clansmen (clanswomen were not included) of the first generation grew to almost six thousand by the seventh. This fecundity, which I believe reflects the ready supply of concubines available to the Chao clansmen more than any unusual fertility on the part of Chao wives, presented the government with two problems.

First, the clan was becoming expensive. In 1067 the monthly support (in cash and grain) for the clan exceeded 70,000 strings, and this did not include expenses for birthdays, marriages, and funerals or the seasonal clothing allowances. This sum compared with 40,000 for the entire capital


136

TABLE 4.1
The Sung Imperial Clan: Generation Names and Membership

Generation No .

T'ai-tsu

T'ai-tsung

Wei-wang

 

Generation Name

No.

Generation Name

No.

Generation
Name

No.

Total

1.

Te

figure

4

Yüan

figure

9

Te

figure

10

23

2.

Wei

figure

8

Yün

figure

19

Ch'eng

figure

32

59

3.

Ts'ung

figure
and Shou
figure

24

Tsung

figure

75

K'o

figure

127

226

4.

Shih

figure

129

Chung

figure

388

Shu

figure

561

1,078

5.

Ling

figure

564

Shih

figure

1,499

Chih

figure

1,425

3,488

6.

Tzu

figure

1,251a

Pu

figure

2,130

Kung

figure

1,774

5,155

7.

Po

figure

1,645

Shan

figure

2,431

Yen

figure

1,824

5,900

8.

Shih

figure

1,490

Ju

figure

1,022

Fu

figure

1,666

4,178

9.

Hsi

figure

1,140

Ch'ung

figure

413

Shih

figure

253

1,806

10.

figure

110

Pi

figure

19

Jo

figure

24

153

Total

 

6,365

 

8,005

 

7,696b

22,066b

SOURCE : CYTC 1.1:24. This information, which CYTC gives in this form though without the totals at the right, is also found in WHTK 259:2056-7, but CYTC is earlier (1203) and the probable source for the WHTK . (The CYTC's source was the Hsien-yuan lei-p'u , the official imperial genealogy.) The table does not include those in the eleventh and twelfth generations, which had been named, nor does it include the direct descendants of Ying-tsung or Hui-tsung or the Nan-pan-kuan clansmen.

aWHTK gives 1,221, but that is an error, for it does not tally with the T'ai-tsu ten-generation total.

bCYTC gives 7,296 and 21,666 respectively, but the Wei-wang total is in fact 7,696 and the grand total 22,066.


137

bureaucracy and 110,000 for the capital armies (SHY:TH 4:31b). Second, the clan in the mid-eleventh century had begun producing children who were not mourning kin of the emperor—that is, beyond the already marginal fifth degree of kinship (t'an-mien ). According to Han and T'ang precedents, they should have been sent out of the capital, given land, and then severed forever from imperial support. This would have solved the problem of the escalating costs of the clan. Yet, in two stages, the late Northern Sung emperors and their reform-minded chief councillors chose to break with tradition and support the nonmourning kin, albeit at reduced levels.

In 1069 the emperor Shen-tsung (r. 1068-85) ordered that kin of the sixth generation and below no longer be given names and official rank by the throne. Records of their births and deaths, however, were still to be maintained, and the men were to be permitted to take special examinations for entry into officialdom (SHY:CK 20:5b-6a). The following year sixth-generation kin were also ordered out of clan housing, a move prompted by severe overcrowding (SHY:CK 20:6a; SHY:TH 4:20b). One noteworthy change that eventually followed from the 1070 order occurred in 1082 when clansmen of the fifth degree and below were permitted, after the death of their parents, to form separate households and divide the family property (except for "fields held in perpetuity" [yung-yeh t'ien ] and sacrificial objects). This practice, standard among commoner families, was said to have "never occurred" in the clan; hitherto, all of their support had come from the government (SHY:TH 5:8a-b). These distant clansmen and women now found themselves in a limbo of partial recognition and limited privilege, which as we shall see below informed their marriage relations as well.

Then, in 1102, chief councillor Ts'ai Ching (1046-1126) proposed an ambitious plan for two large residential complexes called the Halls of Extended Clanship (Tun-tsung yuan ). Supported by charitable estates (i-chuang ) endowed out of local governmental resources, the residences were to be established at the Western and Southern capitals, that is, Lo-yang and Ying-t'ien fu (SHY:CK 20:34a-b). This proposal, which was accepted by the emperor Hui-tsung (r. 1101-25), entailed two new bureaucracies known jointly as the Two Capitals Offices of Imperial Clan Affairs (Liang-ching tsung-cheng-ssu ), which provided housing and support (in the form of cash and grain allowances, wedding and funeral expenses) for these clansmen and women. Their scale was impressive: in 1120 the southern Hall of Extended Clanship reported holdings of 44,000 ch'ing of fields (roughly 660,000 acres) and more than 23,600 rooms (chien ) of buildings (fang-lang ); even then there were complaints about insufficient resources and space (SHY:CK 20:36b-37a).

The decision of Shen-tsung and, then, Hui-tsung to support the non-mourning kin is an interesting issue that can only be touched upon here. Moroto Tatsuo has linked this decision to the Sung policy of elevating the civil over the military and suggests further that it was part of a general Sung


138

ideology of benevolence (onkeishugi ) (1958:628), though he does not say why that benevolence was applied at this time and to the imperial clan. One plausible explanation is that they were influenced by the renewed interest in the tsung (extended kinship group, or clan) voiced by such men as Ou-yang Hsiu (1007-72), Su Hsun (1009-66), and Ch'eng I (1033-1107) (Ebrey 1984a: 229-32). At a time when the scholar-officials were advocating stronger tsung , it would have looked amiss for the emperor to cut off most of the imperial clan, which was the quintessential tsung . This hypothesis, however, will have to await further consideration elsewhere.

The Extended Clanship Halls as well as the clan's entire K'ai-feng establishment came to an abrupt end with the loss of northern China to the Jurchen in 1126, though this was far from the end of the clan. Those who escaped fled pell-mell to the south. By the time a measure of stability and order were restored, the clan had two offices in Fu-chien—at Fu-chou and Ch'üan-chou (continuing the old Western and Southern Capital administrations)—and in Shao-hsing fu (Liang-che-tung) and Lin-an, the capital (CYTC 1.1:25-26). But few Southern Sung clansmen lived at the capital, partly because the government, citing high housing and living costs, early on discouraged them from settling there (SHY:TH 6:12b-13a). The general infertility of the Southern Sung emperors also meant that the clan had few close imperial kin. Thus Fu-chou, Ch'üan-chou, and Shao-hsing prefectures became the main centers of clan resettlement, with Ch'üan-chou claiming some 2,244 clansmen in the early thirteenth century (CWCKCC 15:11a); clansmen could be found in every part of the empire, often supervised only loosely by local officials and clan elders.

The dispersed and diminished circumstances of the imperial clan, however, were paralleled by a growth in the political power of many clan families. Although they had first been permitted to hold local offices (wai-kuan ) in the 1070s, the disordered conditions of the early Southern Sung saw them employed in large numbers to fill vacancies in the bureaucracy and even the army. So widespread were they that quotas were established limiting the numbers of clansmen who could serve in a given county or prefecture (SHY:TH 5:32b-33a). Thereafter, though producing two chief councillors and a number of high-ranking officials in the court, they were most prominent in local government. The Chaos also became a major presence in the examinations, in which they were given preferred treatment (see Chaffee 1985: 106-8). There was a paradox here. The growing numbers and increasing genealogical distance of most Chaos from the emperor led to general reduction in status and affluence, but their humbler, less-threatening position undoubtedly facilitated their assumption of real, if limited, power. Thus they became more like the shih-ta-fu elite even while maintaining their imperial clan status, with its attendant privileges and regulations.

The Sung imperial clan thus underwent radical changes over the course of


139

the dynasty. The wealthy, centralized, though politically powerless clan of the mid-eleventh century bore little resemblance to the Southern Sung clan, which was much humbler and more dispersed, yet contained many individually consequential members. Likewise, there were vast differences between the immediate imperial families, the holders of hereditary noble titles, and the distant kin who were, at times, reduced to poverty.[6] Yet all of them branched from the Son of Heaven in the eyes of the emperor and his officials and were governed by the same sets of concerns and regulations. As we turn to the clanswomen and their marriages, we must therefore keep in mind both the clan's diversity and hierarchy and also its unity, when viewed from the outside.

The Regulation of Marriage

The earliest Sung record of imperial clan marriage regulations dates from 1029, some seventy years into the dynasty, when the proliferation of clans-men was already rendering the less formal nuptial procedures obsolete. Emperor Jen-tsung ordered each clan palace—of which there were ten—to submit a list of clansmen aged eighteen and clanswomen aged fifteen (Chinese style) to be considered for marriages. While specifying administrative procedures including the appointment of eunuch investigators and the emperor's personal approval, the edict goes on to specify that marriage partners "whose talent and age are suitable" should be sought from among "the elite families of examination graduates" (i-kuan shih-tsu ), families without artisans, merchants, or "miscellaneous elements" (tsa-lei ), and with no history of treasonous activities (SHY:CK 20:4b).

Several aspects of this edict deserve comment. First, there was no question that all clan members should marry, and marry young. In contrast to Europe, where a variety of factors combined to limit marriage and therefore fertility, in China fertility was maximized in every way possible, and nowhere was that truer than for the imperial clan. There were, to be sure, clanswomen who became Buddhist or Taoist nuns,[7] but they were exceedingly rare. Second, clan marriages were considered state business in which the young clan member's immediate family had no formal role. The provision requiring the approval of the emperor himself was a mark of the importance accorded them, and as we shall see below the emperor himself at times initiated marriages. There was, finally, a great concern that the marriage partners come from proper families. The proscribed categories of artisan, merchant, and "miscellaneous elements" were the same as those for examination candidates, but the requirement that they come from elite families—which meant families with a history of government service—was not. The government wanted to ensure that its marriage ties were with families from the ruling elite.


140

TABLE 4.2
Imperial Clan Marriage Partners: Proscribed Groups



Year

Imperial Kin Affected (if specified )



Proscribed Marriage Partners

1029

offspring of artisans, merchants, or "miscellaneous elements" or from families with a history of treasonous activities

1077

5th degree

from families of "miscellaneous elements": where males had been slaves or females prostitutes or where parents or grandparents had lived on the border and served two regimes

1077

4th degree and above

offspring of clerks, officials via purchase or special skills, artisans, merchants, "miscellaneous elements," and those with a history of treasonous activities

1088

5th degree and above

same as 4th degree in 1077

1088

relatives of eunuchs

1213

6th degree and above

families of clerks

SOURCES : SHY:CK 20:4b; SS 115:2739; HCP 409:4b; SHY:TH 5:7b, 7:30a-b.

Over the succeeding half-century, this question of the social background of affinal relatives gave rise to a great deal of legislation (table 4.2). In 1058 it was decreed that commoners (pai-shen-jen ) who married clanswomen needed either a three-generation record of office holding or one direct ancestor with at least capital rank, and moreover had to be recommended by a court or capital-rank official (SHY:CK 20:5a; HCP 187:10a). Six years later this was decreased to a flat requirement of two ancestors who had been officials (SS 115:2739), and in 1088 was further reduced, for clan members of the fifth degree, to one official (HCP 409:4b). The proscribed categories also underwent change. In 1077 families of "miscellaneous elements" were defined as those with slaves among the males or prostitutes among the females, and also as those with parents or grandparents who had lived along a border and had served two regimes. Clansmen and women within the fourth degree were barred from marrying the sons or grandsons of clerks, officials who had gained rank via purchase or special skills, in addition to the aforementioned artisans, merchants, and "miscellaneous elements."[8] It was further specified that the required paperwork was the responsibility of the groom's family, though the guarantors, the Office of Imperial Clan Affairs and the Palace Domestic Service, were all legally responsible for the information contained therein (SS 115:2739). Finally, in 1088 the proscriptions for the fourth-degree kin from 1077 were extended to fifth-degree kin (HCP 409:4b), and


141

later that year a further category was added, marriage with the families of eunuchs (nei-ch'en ), on the grounds that because they had access to the palace living quarters, marriage connections with them would be inappropriate (SHY:TH 5:7b).

These provisions dealt only with clan members within the fifth degree of mourning and initially, at least, nonmourning kin were not included. A lengthy memorial from 1069 proposing to restructure the rights and privileges of clan members specified that "nonmourning clanswomen" follow the marriage laws for commoner families, but then added that they "should not marry into nonelite (fei shih-tsu ) families" (ibid., TH 4.33b). This qualification apparently was not included when the restructuring was enacted later that year, for the 1077 and 1088 edicts cited above mention only the use of the laws for commoner families. But by the thirteenth century if not before, restrictions were being applied to the nonmourning kin as well. A memorial by the Great Office of Imperial Clan Affairs in 1213 stated: "Although by law, legitimate imperial clansmen and women of the sixth degree and below are to marry according to the laws for commoner families, the commentaries [chu-wen ] should be cited: that the sons and grandsons from families with miscellaneous elements or with a history of criminals or traitors are unacceptable as [marriage] relations." Further quoting the commentaries on the definition of "miscellaneous elements" (the exact language of the 1077 edict is used), the memorial stated that powerful and wealthy local families were conspiring with "unregistered clansmen" to obtain clan status for the latter and were then marrying them in order to gain official status for themselves. As a consequence, clerical families were thereafter barred from marrying with clansmen (SHY:TH 7:30a-b). I shall return to the issue of official rank as a reward for marriage and the problems associated with it; here it is enough to note that, having accepted the responsibility for continuing to support the nonmourning imperial kin, the government eventually found itself forced to police their marriages as well.

The government's active role in clan marriages was paralleled in other aspects of clanswomen's lives as well. For example, a fairly liberal attitude was taken toward divorce by clansmen and women. It was permitted if there were grounds for separation as spelled out in the law code or even evidence of incompatibility (pu hsiang-an ), but, first, an investigation was required by the Office of Imperial Clan Affairs (SS 115:2739-40; SHY:TH 5:1a).[9] Also, in the philanthropic atmosphere of Hui-tsung's reign, special provisions were made for orphaned clanswomen and childless widows without close relatives to enter the Halls of Extended Clanship and receive an allowance of grain and cash. In addition, remarriage allowances were authorized for clans-women who were nonmourning kin (SHY:CK 20:36a). The following year living quarters at the halls were authorized for orphaned clanswomen and for both legally divorced and widowed clanswomen who had returned to the


142

clan, though if they had living parents, uncles, or brothers, they were required to live with them (SHY:CK 20:36a).

In the Southern Sung these precedents led to an acknowledged responsibility for the care of clan orphans and single women, though often that care took the form of the individuals having the right to draw their allowances from the local government coffers. These allowances were not large—in 1158 they were set at a string of cash and a shih of grain per month for those fifteen sui or over, half that for those younger (SHY: TH 6:30a)—but it was a significant commitment given the large numbers of kin potentially involved. A desire to contain costs could also lead to further regulation of the clans-women's lives; in a memorial from 1162 we find an "unmarried clanswoman who has exceeded her time limit [for marriage]" (wei-hsien wei-chia tsung-nü ) by a year, asking for an additional year to give her relatives time to arrange a marriage. If after that time she were still unmarried, she would receive the lesser allowance of a returned clanswoman (SHY:CK 20:40a). The proposal, which was accepted, is the only reference I have found to such a time limit, but it suggests the degree of involvement in the personal lives of these women that these regulations entailed.

Official Dowries and Marriage Exchanges

One of the underlying reasons for the government's careful regulation of clan marriages was that marriage to a clanswoman brought a family not merely prestige but significant benefits as well. These benefits, or "official dowries" as I shall call them, took a variety of forms, most of them set according to the rank or relationship of the clanswoman to the emperors, past or present.

There was, first, the formal dowry, or lien-chü , the money and goods that the government provided at the woman's marriage. For an imperial princess (kung-chu ), these could be considerable, as the following enumeration from the Sung History's section on wedding ritual suggests: a jade belt with an outer coat, a silver saddle and bridle, and four hundred rolls of fine silk were the gifts stipulated for "joining relatives" (hsi-ch'in ); ten thousand ounces (liang ) of silver formed the "expenses for separating from the imperial household" (pien-ts'ai —twice the amount set aside for princes' betrothal gifts); and following the wedding, the princess was given a mansion (chia-ti ), four fans, ten flower screens, and ten candlestick holders (SS 115:2732). There seems to have been considerable variation in what was actually given, especially in the Northern Sung when emperors were exceptionally generous to their daughters. In 1067 Shen-tsung remarked that the cost of marrying one princess could run to 700,000 strings of cash (JCSP 14:4a-b), while the marriage of Jen-tsung's daughter, the Yen-kuo princess (see Appendix, no. 4), in 1057 involved a dowry of twenty horses, twenty cows, two camels, two hundred sheep, fifty ch'ing of land (about eight hundred acres), three estates, ten


143

slaves, two house officials, and four cooks (SHY:TH 8:11a).[10] Lesser but still sumptuous gifts are also detailed for commandary princesses (chün-chu , the daughters of the heir-apparent) and county princesses (hsien-chu , the daughters of princes, or wang ): a gold belt for hsi-ch'in , five thousand ounces of silver for the pan-ts'ai , with other gifts valued at one-third those of emperors' daughters (SS 115:2732).

All clanswomen were supposed to receive at least some dowry. A dowry scale set during the Hsi-ning period (1068-77) specified five hundred strings for great-great-granddaughters of emperors (yuan-sun-nü ), three hundred and fifty for clanswomen in the fifth generation, three hundred for those in the sixth, two hundred and fifty for those in the seventh, and one hundred and fifty for those in the eighth (CYTC 1.1:25).[11] The dowry amounts specified for the last three of these are of special interest because they were for women who are beyond the mourning circle, thus indicating the government's continuing support of their marriages. In 1137 these dowries were cut by two-fifths for the great-granddaughters, one-third for the sixth- and eighth-generation women, and two-sevenths for those in the fifth and seventh generations. But even so, financially pressed local governments (to which this responsibility had fallen) at times refused to pay. In one instance in 1162 funds for dowry payments had to be specially sent from the court to Ch'üan-chou. As one of the largest clan centers in the empire and the seat of a clan office, Ch'üan-chou had a particularly heavy burden (CYTC 1.1:25). Whether even these reduced dowries continued to be paid through the Southern Sung (especially as increasingly distant generations were produced) is hard to say, but one essay from the mid-thirteenth century suggests that some payments were maintained, though only in a form inadequate to help some unfortunate clanswomen. Fang Ta-ts'ung (1183-1247), himself the brother-in-law of a clanswoman (no. 15, Appendix), wrote in the course of an essay on the fiscal problems of the imperial clan, that,

According to precedent, when clanswomen get married they are to have a cash dowry (tzu-chi ). Now there are those [in families] living outside [the clan residences] who are forced to marry when they have just come of age (at the hairpin ceremony) because [their families are] worried about the money and food they are wasting. Why is it that the prefectural officials do not want to relieve their grievous condition and give them the affection due the Heavenly lake [of imperial kin]? (TAC 26:7a)

Significant as the clanswomen's cash dowries were (and in the 1162 Ch'üan-chou case cited above it was claimed that many poor clanswomen were unwilling to marry without it), even more important were recruitment privileges conferred on the husband and his family, a practice established during the T'ang dynasty (JCSP 16:5b). The basic privilege, as enunciated in 1070, provided the husband with the low military service rank of attendant


144

of the three ranks (San-pan feng-chih —rank 9B). If he were already an official, he was entitled to a promotion of one rank (kuan ) (SHY:TH 4:23b-24a). The promotion privilege had previously been limited to husbands of clanswomen of the fourth-degree kin or above who were already capital-rank officials, but the 1070 edict extended it to all fifth-degree clanswomen's husbands, regardless of their rank or post. For the husbands of commandary and county princesses, a slightly higher initial rank of duty attendant (Tien-chih ) was given, while the husbands of princesses were made commandant-escort (Fu-ma tu-wei ) (SS 115:2732; SMCTI 33:11b-12a). In addition, beginning in 1064 the husbands of clanswomen were permitted to sit for the examinations in the Locked Hall Examination (so-t'ing-shih ), a special preliminary examination for officials). They had previously been excluded from these examinations (SHY:TH 4:15a; HCP 202:1 b-2a).

Although the evidence on recruitment privileges in the Southern Sung is scanty, it would seem that the examinations came to play an important role. According to Hung Mai, writing in the mid-Southern Sung, a commoner marrying a clanswoman of the fifth degree could receive the prestige title of "court gentleman for ceremonial service" (Chiang-shih-lang ) if he were a chü-jen (that is, had passed the preliminary examinations); if not, he received the honorary military title of "gentleman for fostering temperance" (Ch'eng-chieh-lang ) or "gentleman of trust" (Ch'eng-hsin-lang ), both titles being equivalent to the Northern Sung "attendant of the three ranks." Although nominally higher than the civil rank, these designations were nevertheless less desirable because they were military (JCSP 16:5b). Whether these privileges were restricted to the marriages of mourning kin, however, is not entirely clear. If so, the vast majority of Southern Sung clanswomen would have been excluded. Li Hsin-ch'uan, a contemporary of Hung's, wrote that "those who have passed the preliminary examinations who marry clanswomen may enter the civil service" (CYTC 2.14:534). In a number of the cases discussed below, the husbands of Southern Sung clanswomen made use of their recruitment privileges. This evidence, together with Hung's assertion, suggests that the privileges were broadly applied.

Finally, the Southern Sung husbands of clanswomen were given the additional privilege of naming one son to office through protection, or yin (CYTC 1.6:86). Introduced in 1166, this privilege was separate from other protection privileges the husband might gain through his own or his family's accomplishments and further supports the notion of a liberal dispensation of recruitment privileges for clanswomen (or their husbands) in the Southern Sung. Indeed, it may be that as the state's ability to support lavish dowries declined, the government compensated in part with a lenient policy toward recruitment privileges, however shortsighted that would have been in the long run.

This legislated combination of dowry and privileges raises the question of the exchanges involved in clanswomen's marriages. These exchanges were


145

like the royal dowries common to most European monarchial systems in that they drew on the resources of the state. But where royal marriages, in Europe at least, were made with other royalty as well as the nobility, in China there was no other royalty. Although it is true that in certain periods (such as the non-Han dynasties discussed by Holmgren and Rawski elsewhere in this volume) imperial clan marriages were used as an instrument of foreign policy, this seems not to have been the case during the Sung; indeed, imperial princesses without exception married Han Chinese. Whereas the largest royal dowries, like that of the Yen-kuo princess cited above, were personally tailored to women of the immediate royal family, the official marriage benefits for all other brides were impersonal, bureaucratic, and employed on a vast scale.

This evidence admittedly comes from the realm of political legislation rather than anthropological description. Still, assuming that the dowry legislation was largely adhered to (and for the Northern Sung at least that would seem reasonable), we can still ask after clan marriage exchanges. The state's role on behalf of the clan created such an asymmetry in the marriages as to render inapplicable much of the anthropological literature on dowry, such as Spiro's notion of economic exchange or Goody's of diverging devolution (Comaroff 1980: 3-8). Levi-Strauss's structural notion of marriage as a system of women for women exchanges (ibid., 26) is more useful, with the emperor, through the imperial clan, providing the ruling elite with women, dowries, and privileges, while the ruling elite reciprocated with women, loyalty, and service. Unlike the cultural structures that Levi-Strauss has so remarkably articulated, however, this structure was the invention of politics and was one of the building blocks of the Sung political order.

In their attempt to consolidate power and create a stable order, the early Sung emperors worked systematically to limit the power of all potential rivals, be they the military, families of empresses, great families with long traditions of office holding, or, as we have seen, the imperial clan. Their chief partner in this was the civil elite, which owed its position largely to land, wealth, the examinations, and bureaucratic achievement and was more broadly based than ever before. I would suggest that imperial marriages formed a part of that partnership, for they demonstrated imperial beneficence. The blessings of such marriages were admittedly mixed, for hypogamous unions put a strain on the grooms' families, as will be seen below; but the wealth, office, and potential influence still made such marriages attractive.

During the Southern Sung the government's role in deciding marriage matches seems to have ceased. The clanswomen's inscriptions speak in places of individual go-betweens and, once, of the need for official approval for the woman's husband to receive official rank but not at all of the government or clan organizations initiating and arranging marriages. Thus, if there had been broad political goals behind clan marriages in the Northern Sung,


146

they must have disappeared, or at least have been greatly diluted, during the Southern Sung.

Another factor was at work apart from politics: that of honor. Honor, of course, was one of the assets the imperial clan had to offer. To quote Wang Meng-lung, who married Chao Ju-i (Appendix, no. 13; 1183-1221), "The honor of his wife is what a husband relies upon; the wealth of a husband is what contents his wife. This is certainly the rule when common families marry with the imperial clan" (SHWC 25:11a-12a). There was a concomitant fear of dishonor. The recruitment privileges, in one respect a measure of imperial grace, thus increasingly served to maintain the clan's respectability because they made even humble clanswomen attractive to elite families. In 1070 Wang An-shih argued in favor of a proposal to extend promotion privileges to officials marrying fifth-degree clanswomen: "This is a way of encouraging those who are officials to marry clanswomen and also [provides] a shortcut for entering officialdom" (SHY:TH 4:23b-24a; HCP 213:7a-b).

Wang was concerned not so much with making useful political connections for the emperor as ensuring that clanswomen and the clan itself be spared from improper marriages. In this he was not alone, for a recurring theme in writings on clanswomen's marriages was that they should not dishonor or sully the imperial clan. People did not always agree upon what constituted dishonor, however. In 1051 the head of the Bureau of Policy Criticism, Pao Cheng (998-1061), vehemently protested the pending marriage of a clanswoman to the son of one Li Shou, the former owner of an alum shop who had become an official via purchase. This match had been investigated and approved by censors and the Office of Imperial Clan Affairs, who declared that "this is not a family of skilled artisans or itinerant merchants." In other words, the regulations were designed to ensure an elite life-style and status (even if purchased) rather than ancestral background. Pao did not agree, arguing that suitable matches could be made only with families of renown and that "ritual teachings" (li-chiao ) must be followed strictly (SMCTI 33:10b-11a).

The sources do not reveal the outcome of Pao Cheng's objections, but his suggestion that clanswomen's marriages into "upstart" families violated the natural order was echoed by others. In 1068 the censor Liu Shu (1034 chin-shih ), in arguing unsuccessfully that clanswomen's marriages be restricted to currently serving civil and military officials, asserted that wealthy villagers falsely used the official genealogies of others to marry clanswomen. "For entangling the rules of the country," he wrote, "and dirtying that which is under Heaven, there is nothing worse than this" (SMCTI 33:11b-12a).

Even more remarkable, metaphorically and substantively, is a 1088 memorial by the drafting official P'eng Ju-li (1041-94) asking for a clarification of the marriage regulations for fifth-degree (t'an-mien ) clansmen anti women. Noting that fifth-degree kin are barred from marrying into "nonelite families" (fei shih-tsu chih chia ), he said he did not know what constitutes


147

"elite families" because the specific occupational prohibitions applied only to fourth-degree kin, thus opening the way to marriages with officials via purchase and even those with treasonous backgrounds. He then continued:

In my opinion, that which accumulates greatly will flow lengthily and when far from the source will form a great lake. That is the nature of things. Now among the Son of Heaven's kin, if the ancestors reaching to the seventh generation are not forgotten, then their descendants stretching into the distance also cannot but be acclaimed. Even though the fifth-degree kin have all issued from the imperial ancestors and are identically connected to the body of the state (kuo-t'i ), they are made dirty, rustic and remote, and all can be taken [in marriage] as commodities. This does not honor the imperial ancestors. (SMCTI 33:12b-13a)

The consequences of this he then paints in vivid if melodramatic colors:

Powerful merchants and great traders, using wealth to dominate their communities, now pay from three to five thousand strings of cash to enter [officialdom] as instructors and registrars, and so steal the name of "elite family" (shih-tsu ). By further payment of several thousand strings, they can seek to become palace kin [i.e., marry with the imperial clan] and thus gain the status of "official household" (kuan-hu ). Stealing favor, robbing the state, relying on force, and humiliating the weak, how can this not be a disgrace to the state? (SMCTI 33:13a)

With this last assertion, P'eng adds a dimension to our notions of clan marriage exchanges, for here we see a different, sub-rosa, exchange of money for marriage and its attendant office, or at least allegations of it. The 1213 memorial mentioned above, which alleged conspiracies between powerful, wealthy families and unregistered clansmen, suggests his accusation had some basis in fact. We cannot say whether such exchanges were common, but given the clan's reduced circumstances in the Southern Sung it would not be surprising if they were.[12]

Even more interesting are the images the memorial uses and the attitudes they reveal. Although the common Sung metaphor for the imperial clan was "branches of Heaven" (T'ien chih ), P'eng talks of the "body of the state," which can be sullied (thus echoing Liu Shu), but even more about a stream that flows to make a lake (recalling Fang Ta-ts'ung's earlier quoted reference to the "Heavenly lake of imperial kin"). His concern is with the purity of the imperial kin, and that was most threatened by the marriage of women. Because clanswomen had issued from the Son of Heaven, their husbands could pollute the ever-widening Heavenly lake.[13]

The Affines

Whom did the clanswomen marry and where did they come from? Our biographical evidence for married princesses and clanswomen is limited, but


148

taken together with other kinds of information, two hypotheses may be ventured. First, we know from the regulations described above that they were required to draw from the pool of bureaucratic families. And despite the complaints just discussed about merchants marrying into the clan, it is probable that until the late eleventh century at least, this requirement was largely fulfilled, for the clan was sufficiently small and concentrated. It would also make sense that the Northern Sung clanswomen generally married men whose families were either native to K'ai-feng or had settled there by virtue of official service. Because the imperial clan resided exclusively in K'ai-feng until the 1070s and did not move elsewhere in appreciable numbers until after 1102, K'ai-feng society would have been the natural focus of their marriage ties. K'ai-feng families so dominated the Northern Sung examinations (see Chaffee 1985:61-66) that the capital had plenty of bureaucratic families to supply spouses.

The available evidence supports the first hypothesis and is ambiguous about the second. The wives of Northern Sung clansmen came overwhelmingly from K'ai-feng families; of the fifty-seven wives of clansmen in Aoyama Sadao's guide to biographies, forty-eight (84 percent) of the fifty-seven clansmen's wives for whom family residence is known came from Kai-feng.[14] Of the other nine, six came from the north China plain and two others came from long-established and successful bureaucratic families in Lang-chou (Ssu-ch'uan) and Hang-chou (Liang-che-hsi).[15] In striking contrast to the marriages of clansmen, the husbands of Northern Sung princesses and clanswomen came predominantly from non-K'ai-feng families; of twenty-two for whom information about residency is available (Appendix, nos. 3-7, 20, 23-25, 27-28, 30-32, 36-37, 40-43, 45-46), nineteen came from provincial, predominantly northern families.[16] This does not mean that the husbands themselves were provincials; because most came from long-established families with records of high military or civil office, they had probably spent much or all of their youths in the capital. Still, such wide-ranging family origins suggest an attention to provincial alliances on the part of the Sung emperors.

Priscilla Ching Chung, in her study of Northern Sung palace women, found that the dynasty drew heavily from military families and very little from scholarly families. She points to T'ai-tsu's famous drinking speech to his generals, in which he offers to intermarry his family with theirs, as evidence of a kind of military alliance marriage strategy (1981: 24-35). Jennifer Holmgren, while agreeing with Chung, has argued further that a key element of such a marriage policy was that the military elite was declining and therefore did not pose a threat to the bureaucratic elite (see her chapter in this volume). The princesses' marriages generally support that finding, for nine husbands were from prominent military families (nos. 23, 25, 30-32, 36, 40-41, 44), compared to five from high-ranking civil families (5, 20, 27, 43,


149

37) and two from scholarly families (nos. 28, 42).[17] But these figures obscure an important change in the husbands over time. In the early Sung princesses married military men almost exclusively. By the late Northern Sung not only were husbands chosen more frequently from scholarly and high civil families, but husbands from military families appear to have turned civil. Ch'ien Ching-chen (husband of no. 23), the scion of the royal Ch'iens of Wu-yüeh and subsequently of early Sung generals, was known for his learning and activities as a local official in the south (Ch'ang et al. 1974-765:4085), and Wang Shih-yueh (1044-1102; husband of no. 40), offspring of the early Sung general Wang Shen-ch'i, was the son of a chin-shih and classically educated (ibid., 1:335). Moreover, being related to empresses could also be important, as was the case with nos. 3, 4, and 27. Thus, by the late Northern Sung, family and personal ties with the palace or ministerial service had largely replaced military considerations in determining clanswomen's marriages.

One other intriguing piece of evidence suggests that by the late Northern Sung, the clanswomen's recruitment privileges were already proving potent attractions for wealthy but undistinguished families. With echoes of P'eng Ju-li, Chu Yü wrote in 1119:

In recent generations since clanswomen have become numerous, the [Office of] Clan Affairs has established several score official matchmakers to handle marriage discussions. Initially there were no limitations [with regard to] influential and wealthy families, and many gave gifts to the clan in their quest for matches, illicitly seeking an office so as to protect their households. Thereafter [these families and the clan] have sought each other out as kin. Rich people of the capital like the Ta-t'ung Chang family have married with as many as thirty or more county princesses. (PCKT 1:3-4)

The Southern Sung spouses exhibit quite different characteristics from their Northern Sung predecessors. First, they were truly dispersed geographically; none of them appears to have lived at the capital: four spouses came from the Chiang-nan circuits (no. 8 from Jao-chou, no. 9 from Fu-chou, no. 10 from Chi-chou, and no. 18 from Hung-chou), four from Liang-che-tung (nos. 12 and 14 from Ming-chou, no. 11 from Wu-chou and no. 13 from T'ai-chou), and three from Fu-chien (nos. 14 and 16 from Hsing-hua and no. 17 from Ch'üan-chou). This distribution was generally matched by the families of the clanswomen, but with a number of interesting differences. There are no indications that the families of nos. 8-12 and 17-18 lived in different prefectures from those of their husbands (although most of the inscriptions do not assert that their prefecture was the same), but the cousins Chao Ju-chieh (no. 15) and Pi-shan (no. 16) both moved from Ch'üan-chou, the seat of the Southern Imperial Clan Office, up the coast to Hsing-hua chun, and Chao Hsi-i (no. 14) moved from T'ai-chou north to Yin County of Ming-chou. Most remarkably, the family of Chao Ju-i (no. 13) was from Ch'ih-


150

chou in Chiang-nan-tung, but she married Yuan Fu of Ming-chou, hundreds of miles to the east. These findings are interesting in the light of recent studies of Sung marriage patterns that have argued that the Southern Sung elites, in contrast to their Northern Sung counterparts, married predominantly with families from their own prefectures (see Hartwell 1982 and especially Hymes 1986). The Chaos, it would appear, were atypical and married more widely, though the precise social mechanisms for their doing so are still unclear.[18]

The social backgrounds of the Southern Sung husbands also differ from those in the Northern Sung. With the possible exception of the interregional bride Chao Ju-i, whose three-generation genealogy is not given, the clans-women's forebears were almost all officials, less exalted in rank but including many who had been active officials, which agrees with what we know about the clan in the Southern Sung.[19] Like their fathers and fathers-in-law, the Southern Sung husbands with just one exception (Lo Chin, the husband of no. 18) were or became officials. Two received chin-shih degrees (the husbands of nos. 13-14), in both cases after their marriages, and their wives are praised for their support. One husband, as we note above, entered via protection. We do not know how another four qualified for office (the husbands of nos. 8-9 and 12-13). Four husbands, however, either used their wives' privileges or explicitly chose not to do so. They thus merit further attention because their cases reveal a good deal about the use of this privilege and attitudes toward it.

For Lady Chao (no. 11), marriage to Hsu Shih came at the relatively late age of twenty-seven sui . Because the groom reportedly made the match "in the hopes of obtaining office and establishing his family," Lady Chao's privileges probably saved her from a life of spinsterhood. In writing about this, the philosopher Ch'en Liang (1143-94), who had been a friend of Hsu Shih's late father, Chieh-ch'ing, was initially dismayed: "I strongly regretted this [as it was] contrary to Chieh-ch'ing's intentions." He changed his mind, however, for he found that Shih "has increasingly worked at his studies and lately I have seen that his writings have daily improved." Moreover, upon meeting her, Ch'en found that she was "really unlike the daughter of a noble family" and had delighted even her mother-in-law. But then she died after just 130 days of marriage, much to everyone's distress (CLC 29:431).

In the case of Lady Chao of Lu-ling (no. 10), it was the husband who shared Ch'en's dislike of clanswomen's recruitment privileges, lacking as they did the prestige of more regular avenues. For years after their marriage, he disdained using his wife's privileges and lived the life of a poor aspiring scholar, studying, instructing his sons, and entertaining his fellow literati. Even after his younger brothers, a nephew, and many of his friends all became officials and he became an embittered recluse, he did not waver in this. At her suggestion, however, he sent some of his writings to the chief councillor


151

Chou Pi-ta (1126-1204), who upon reading them recommended him for office (CCC 129:10b-12a). Not all spurned the clanswomen's privileges, however. Fang Ta-yü (1181-1234), the husband of Chao Pi-shan (no. 16), passed the Hsing-hua prefectural examination in 1204 and availed himself of his wife's privilege immediately after failing the metropolitan examination the next year (HTHSTCC 151:11a-12a; TAC 34:2a-b, 35:3b). Ch'iu Shuang, the husband of Pi-shan's cousin, Shan-i (no. 17), also used his wife's privileges, but the matter was complicated and thus instructive. Ch'iu had agreed to marry Shan-i, an orphan, on the recommendation of her cousin and guardian, who had praised her highly and also undoubtedly pointed out the advantages in it for Ch'iu, for according to the inscription,

Mr. Ch'iu had once been recommended in the local [examinations], so since he had married [a clanswoman], by the regulations of the Prince of P'u's House, he was supposed to receive office. But because there were those obstructing it, it seemed that it would have to be settled at the capital. Ju-jen [i.e., his wife Shan-i] said, "My oldest sister is married in Liang-che. We have long been separated and I have wanted to see her once [again]. Why don't we go together?" When Ch'iu finally received entry rank she was delighted but also encouraged him saying, "Scholars are supposed to achieve [success] on their own and not simply wait for imperial grace." Then suddenly, he was recommended for a post in [Liang-]che. She was very happy that he had gained a position of respect and established his name. (HTHSTCC 150:18a-b)

This passage is frustrating in its omissions—did they ever visit her sister?—but still instructive. The use of privilege we see, not as an automatic matter, but as a bureaucratic affair subject to delays and influence. The reference to the prince of P'u—the father of Emperor Ying-tsung (r. 1064-67)—is also interesting because all four of these clanswomen whose recruitment privilege was used or discussed were from that branch. Is this a coincidence or were they particularly favored? (Certainly they were all of humbler birth than the county princesses alluded to by Chu Yü earlier.) Because I know of no regulations according them special treatment, it must be left an open question. Perhaps most interesting is Shan-i herself. Although willing to use family connections to help her husband gain office, she appears to share the general disdain for relying exclusively on privilege. In fact, at the time of her premature death at twenty-eight sui , her husband was away sitting for the examinations, seeking the prestige and career advantages that accompanied the chin-shih degree.

The Issue of Inequality

Imperial clanswomen entered marriage with considerable resources of their own. Apart from their official dowries and such gifts that their families and friends (or the emperor) might have bestowed on them personally, the most


152

noteworthy were noble titles. These ranged in rank order from the exalted commandery princess (chün-chu ) and county princess (hsien-chu ) mentioned above, through lady of virtue (shu-jen ), lady of eminence (shih-jen ), lady of excellence (ling-jen ), respectful lady (kung-jen ), lady of suitability (i-jen ), lady of peace (an-jen ) to the humblest title, child nurturess (ju-jen ).[20] In our group of fourteen (not counting the princesses), one was named consort of state (kuo-fu-jen , no. 7), one was a commandery lady (no. 3), two were ladies of suitability (nos. 9 and 14), two ladies of peace (nos. 12 and 15), and four were child nurturesses (nos. 13 and 16-18). In four cases no titles were mentioned (nos. 6, 8, and 10-11).

Commandery and county princesses received biannual clothing allowances plus monthly cash and grain stipends. From Hung Mai's example of a county lady receiving a stipend of almost one hundred strings of cash, it is clear that allowances could be substantial (JCSP 3.14:4a-b). Although no stipends are mentioned for the lesser-ranked ladies, all titled clanswomen were granted recruitment privileges for their sons, which apparently were different from the earlier-mentioned privileges for their husbands: all could have one son or grandson named to receive official rank upon their deaths, and commandery and county princesses could also name offspring after they had attended two suburban sacrifices—the former could name four, the latter one (CYTC 2.14:531).

Titles as such were not unique to clanswomen; wives of clansmen and important officials were also titled. But few other wives from nonclan families could begin to match the influence that was the clanswomen's by virtue of their imperial connections, influence that some put to use. The emperor Kao-tsung (r. 1126-62) rebuked one princess for repeatedly asking him to promote her husband and on another occasion gently chastised an elderly princess for favoring her own son over her stepsons, although this did not stop him from meeting either of their demands (SS 248:8782, 8775).

In addition, the rights and privileges of early Sung princesses were at odds with some of the basic patriarchal principles of Chinese society. They lived, not with their in-laws, but in the mansions provided upon marriage. In the late 1060s the Wei-kuo great senior princess (no. 42) brought her mother-in-law, who had been living alone since her son's marriage, to live in a guest-house and plied her with delicacies (SS 248:8779). Half a century earlier the Yang-kuo great senior princess (no. 43) had been ordered by her brother, Chen-tsung (r. 997-1022), to use female ritual forms (fu-li ) when visiting her father-in-law's mansion (SS 248:8773). That she was commanded to do what other women did as a matter of course is explained in the biography of the Ching-kuo great senior princess (no. 30):

In the old system, the imperial son-in-law reduced his father to the genealogical level of sibling. At the time [the princess's husband, Li] Tsun-hsu's father,


153

Chi-ch'ang, was deathly ill, and on Chi-ch'ang's birthday the princess visited him using a daughter-in-law's rituals (chiu-li ). The emperor [Chen-tsung] on hearing of this, secretly sent various clothes, a precious belt and utensils to help him live long. (SS 248:8774)

The Sung had inherited a system that claimed imperial prerogatives overrode considerations of generation and gender. But this did not sit well with the dynasty's Confucian principles, so the emperors themselves led the change, Indeed, as early as 1064 the imperial clan's etiquette regulations stated that "imperial clanswomen shall all serve their parents-in-law and their husband's relatives as if they were from the families of subjects" (SS 115:2739).

Such a rule only highlighted, however, the dilemma of reconciling the clanswomen's status as offspring of the Son of Heaven with their roles as wives and daughters-in-law. In the eyes of their (male) critics and biographers, there were two related problems. One was a belief that the clans-women, by virtue of their luxurious and sheltered upbringing, tended to be arrogant and spoiled. Although there was undoubtedly some truth to this perception, it should be noted that scholar-officials of the eleventh century had little sympathy for aristocratic life-styles. But even when the clans-woman was a model wife, the power and privilege of her imperial connection could be problematical for her husband's family. The tension between the competing inequalities of gender subordination and political hierarchy was hardly unique to imperial clanswomen, but it was acute for them and thus central to our understanding of their marriage relationships. In the remaining pages of this chapter I examine several specific cases stemming from these problems and consider the responses to them.

Both arrogance and imperial influence were evident in the case of the Yen-kuo princess. A favorite daughter of the emperor Jen-tsung, she had received a lavish dowry in 1057, described above, when she married Li Wei, the nephew of Jen-tsung's late mother the Chang-i empress (and therefore her cousin). She was given the unprecedented Yen-kuo title in 1061 despite protests that the designation was not mentioned in the ritual writings (SMCTI 33:2b-4a). Despite this special attention—or possibly because of it—an air of notoriety surrounded her. In 1060 she was criticized for using her influence to obtain a promotion for her wet nurse's (ju-mu ) nephew (SHY:TH 8:11b). The following year a controversy erupted between the princess and her husband's family that greatly upset the aged emperor and ended the marriage.

The trouble began when the princess was drinking one day with a eunuch, Liang Huai-chi, who served as her house manager, and saw her mother-in-law, Lady Yang, watching her. Infuriated, she beat Lady Yang, who then reported the matter to the emperor. Jen-tsung found his daughter and Liang


154

to blame and apparently ordered him and another eunuch removed from her household.[21] But when the princess then became hysterical and suicidal and tried to set her palace on fire, the emperor relented, although over the protests of Ssu-ma Kuang and other officials. The princess's palace supporters, after spying on Li Wei and trying unsuccessfully to gather incriminating evidence on him, nevertheless approached the emperor with unspecified accusations against Li. Jen-tsung's first response to this was silence, but after appeals by the empress and an attendant to the memory of his mother, he finally acted (this was in the first month of 1162) by confining the princess to the palace, sending Li Wei out as prefect of Wei-chou (in Ho-pei-hsi), sending Lady Yang to live with another son, exiling Liang Huai-chi, and dismissing various eunuchs who had been involved (HCP 196:4b-5b). This did not end matters, however. Once in Wei-chou, Li was apparently framed on charges of embezzling grain from the public granaries and exiled, while Liang Huai-chi's exile was canceled (SMCTI 33:6b-7b). In response to Li Wei's disgrace, his brother submitted a petition for him requesting a divorce, stating that "Wei is ignorant and stupid, inadequate to receive Heavenly grace, and so asks to be given a divorce." Before the emperor concurred, however, Ssu-ma Kuang delivered a passionate defense of Li. Reminding the emperor that the original intention behind the marriage had been to honor them, Ssu-ma stated: "Now Wei has been separated from his mother, their family has become outcast in its affairs, great and small are grieving [for them], and it may even [reach the point that they will be] unable to make a living" (HCP 196:6a; SMCTI 33:8a). Appealing once again to the memory of the Chang-i empress, whose death anniversary had just past, Ssu-ma asked for Li's return and greater acknowledgment of the princess's guilt. His appeal succeeded. The emperor demoted the princess to the lesser title of I-kuo princess (the only such demotion to occur in the Sung), citing her ill manners, troublesomeness, and disobedience (STCLC 40:215). He also granted the divorce but gave Li Wei two hundred liang of gold as a sign of his esteem (HCP 196:6a-b), saying, "Men of wealth and nobility need not all be imperial sons-in-law" (HCP 196:6a-b). He might have added that those who were need take great care.

Thirty-two years later another princess's marriage relations became a point of controversy, though in a different way. The Ts'ao-kuo princess,[22] one of the emperor Shen-tsung's three surviving daughters, was married in 1090 to Han Chia-yen, the son of the late chief councillor Han Ch'i (1008-75) and brother of Han Chung-yen (1038-1109), who headed the Bureau of Military Affairs from 1092 to 1096. The marriage, which was imperially ordered to honor the memory of Han Ch'i (SS 248:8780), was not a great success. Han was reportedly "lacking in decorum and disrespectful" toward his wife and would spend the night away from their residence without warn-


155

ing. As a punishment, he was censured and exiled to Ch'i-chou in Huai-nan-hsi (HCPSP 9:6b).

Then in a remarkable memorial, the outspoken P'eng Ju-li came to the defense of Han Chia-yen (SMCTI 33:8b-10b). P'eng begins with the familiar argument that the governance of the state, the family, and the husband-wife relationship are interrelated, stating: "If the distinctions between husband and wife are not proper, then when [the ruler] desires that his family affairs be ordered, the family's governance will fail, and as for desiring that the state be ordered, such a thing has never happened" (ibid., 9a). The ideal relationship, he suggests, is epitomized by the king's daughter in the Book of Odes, of whose wedding carriage it was said: "Are they not expressive of reverence and harmony,—The carriages of the king's daughters?" (Legge 1960:35). This may seem obscure, but P'eng explains that, "While the magnificence of the king's daughter's carriage and clothes are fitting for one who is noble and proud, she still upholds the way of the wife, and that is what makes her beautiful. Serving [her husband] she is subordinate, though originally she was above him" (SMCTI 33:9a). P'eng then turns to the case at hand, observing: "Now, because Chia-yen has been unable to subordinate the imperial princess, he has been discarded. This is a case of the wife gaining victory over her husband. If wives are able to gain victory over their husbands, then sons will defeat their fathers and subjects will defeat their ruler. If this source is once loosed, the stream will grow until it cannot be stopped" (ibid., 9a-b). Again, slightly later, he cautions: "Now if you cause wives to deceive their husbands, then in human relations [people will] revolt against their superiors, and customs will decay among those below" (ibid., 10a). Arguing that "small disputes" of a day and night should not be allowed to harm the "great love of a lifetime," P'eng ends by urging the emperor not to oppose his married relatives, so that his great ministers would then not dare to oppose him; thus might the stability of the state be ensured (ibid., 10a-b).

P'eng clearly thought that Han's shortcomings did not merit his punishment and thus shifted the blame to the princess, presumably for going to her brother the emperor rather than submitting quietly as a good wife should. We do not know whether his memorial, with its veiled threat to the young Che-tsung (r. 1086-1100) (a telling indication of the power and assurance of great families like the Hans) had any effect. What is interesting is his categorical insistence on the authority of the husband and the subordination of the wife, however exalted her family. This subordination, inconceivable for a princess in the early Sung, was largely unquestioned in our cases here of Southern Sung clanswomen. But before turning to them, let us digress briefly to consider one clanswoman whose assertiveness appears not to have interfered with her marriage.

From the time her mother was pregnant and her grandmother dreamed


156

that a beautiful and brilliantly dressed young girl had descended from space (HCCSC 41:2b), Chao Tzu-chen (1097-1140), as seen in Sun Ti's lengthy inscription for her, had a dreamlike, larger than life character. Although she Was apparently raised outside of K'ai-feng as a seventh-generation descendent of T'ai-tsung, not an imperial mourning kin, her family seems to have commanded considerable respect. At her birth she was given presents by five families, and she married Yang Ts'un-chung (1102-66) from a prominent Tai-chou family of generals. At the time of the Jurchen invasion, with her husband away in the wars, Tzu-chen was instrumental in aiding local defense forces in Liang-che (after the family moved south, which is not mentioned), providing shelter for loyal soldiers, feeding the hungry, as well as directing the education of her children inasmuch as she was well educated in poetry and writing (ibid., 2a-3b). When the court was established in Lin-an, she became friendly with the imperial children, was given twice-monthly visiting privileges at the imperial palaces and five "national lady" titles. During the illness that led to her premature death, the emperor ordered her treated by imperial doctors (kuo-i ) (ibid., 1b).

Most interesting, however, were Tzu-chen's private activities. Through her stress on her children's education, Tzu-chen is credited with the civilianizing of the family, for her two sons both received chin-shih degrees and had successful civil careers (ibid., 4b, 5b). She was a devout Taoist "whose only delight lay in the study of the Yellow Emperor and Lao-tzu" (ibid., 4a). With a monthly stipend from her titles, which at one point accumulated to ninety thousand cash, she was also a noted philanthropist, providing relief to the hungry during a famine, supporting more than one hundred poor families on land she owned, and, most remarkably, providing the dowries of eighty-three orphaned young women (ibid., 4a-b).

With her many activities and accomplishments, Chao Tzu-chen was hardly typical of even privileged clanswomen or wives of high officials. Assisted by her clan status, she was able to use the opportunities created by the war and resettlement of the court and, through her ability and the force of her character, to make a mark for herself in Lin-an society of the 1130s. Still, one might ask how it was that she avoided the kinds of marital problems that we have seen above. That her husband was away at war (in all he fought in more than one hundred engagements and eventually rose to command the capital army) and was thus seldom at home undoubtedly helped (Ch'ang et al. 4:3163-64). But even more important is that her successes did not interfere with her acting as a model wife and mother, at least in the eyes of her biographer. Tzu-chen is praised for her humble life—eating simple food and doing laundry—in the years before the war when her husband, though talented, was ill-humored and without official rank (HCCSC 41:2b). As we noted earlier, she is credited with directing her sons' education and commended for running a serious and proper household establishment (3a). Together with


157

service to one's in-laws (which is not mentioned, perhaps because her father-in-law and his father both died early in the Jurchen war), these were the essential tasks of the Sung literati wife. As we shall now see, it was mainly for these activities that Southern Sung clanswomen were praised.

If Chao Tzu-chen could be said to represent the imperial clanswomen at their social and political apex, Lady Chao (no. 6; 1121-58) in an equally remarkable way might be said to represent them at their humblest. A sixth-generation descendent of T'ai-tsung and thus not a mourning kin, she became at the age of eighteen sui the second wife (chi-shih ) of Hung Shou-ch'ing, an official from a large and prominent Jao-chou family.

In any event, once with the Hungs, Lady Chao's good breeding, obedience, and equable behavior made her very popular in the large household, which had some thirty brothers and cousins in her husband's generation, and in time she became renowned in the community at large. Her biographer, Hung Kua (himself a cousin of Shou-ch'ing's), relates that for some thirteen years (until she was thirty) the Hungs feared she would be taken back by her family to be married to someone else. Then, when she was thirty-three, her father, who had just become magistrate of Lin-ch'uan county in Fu-chou, sent his younger brother with a beautiful carriage to fetch her from the Hungs, with the apparent intention of making a better match for her elsewhere. But Lady Chao angrily refused to go, saying, "With my mother-in-law elderly and two sons young and foolish, I dare not trouble my seniors. My parents with various schemes cannot suddenly take me away" (PCWC 75: 6b). Asking his leave, she went back into the house and thereafter devoted herself to Hung family affairs, passing on to others gifts sent by her clan relatives, keeping peace in the women's quarters, and, in particular, nursing her mother-in-law. After she collapsed while dining with her mother-in-law and died at the age of just thirty-eight, she was mourned by one and all. The next year, however, she was posthumously titled and buried in imperial clan tombs (ibid., 7b).

The Hungs' just fears of losing Lady Chao, whose marriage was perfectly valid and legal, points to the high-handedness of clan families and makes Lady Chao's passionate commitment to the Hungs, particularly to her mother-in-law, all the more striking. Indeed, in Hung Kua's eyes she assumes heroic proportions. Having praised her for sticking to her principles when her family tried to reclaim her (ibid., 6b), Hung closes the inscription by comparing her with Po Chi from the state of Sung in the Spring and Autumn period, who, as Sung was being conquered and the palace destroyed, refused to leave the palace without her governess (fu-mu ) and thus perished in the flames (ibid., 7b).[23] Just as Po Chi was able to act morally despite living in a dissolute age, so Hung marvels that this imperial clanswoman was able to maintain her integrity at a time when arrogance and licentiousness were common in renowned and exalted families.


158

This theme of virtue in spite of high birth runs like a refrain through many of the inscriptions:

Although born noble and proud, she was frugal not wasteful, respectful not reckless, living in a poor and simple manner. (no. 6; MLCM 6: 47a)

She was totally unlike the children of noble families. (no. 11; CLC 29: 431)

At the time of her marriage, the literati all said, "The wife is of a noble type; they will not necessarily be happy together." However, she was reverent in her wifely rituals; her in-laws praised her filiality; [in acting by] the code of feminine conduct she was serious; towards her [husband's] kinsmen she was respectful. (no. 16; HTHSTCC 158:13b)

She served her in-laws from dawn to dusk . . . People did not know [from her actions] that she had the nobility of a Heavenly clan. (no. 10; CCC 129:10b)

She was by nature noble and pure, without the bad habits of clanswomen. (no. 14; MCC 18:256)

We must take care to avoid assuming that all or even most clanswomen were like those described above. We are after all dealing with the inscriptions of the few clanswomen who for one reason or other had impressed their contemporaries. Besides, phrases such as "the bad habits of clanswomen" could have arisen either from problems families had had with clanswomen as marriage partners or from anticlan bias among the elite. Whichever the case, this evidence is revealing of contemporary attitudes about how married clans-women should behave. They should not be spoiled, they should cheerfully fulfill their roles as wives and daughters-in-law, and they should devote themselves frugally and ascetically to promoting the fortunes of their new families, even when their husbands were leading cultured and leisured lives as private scholars (see, for example, CCC 129:10b-12a). To cite one last example, Chao Ju-i's (no. 13) husband, Wang Meng-lung, described their life while he was a struggling examination candidate (he received his chin-shih in 1208) in these terms:

I went through the successes and failures of the examinations no less than ten times, and each time was away from her for a year. [I would return] to find my sons named, my daughters nurtured and suddenly grown up, and I did not yet even know them. But this is just the norm for the wives of literati. Lady Chao forgot that she was a noble imperial clanswoman and delighted in being the wife of a poor literatus. (SHWC 25:11a)

Chao Ju-i's life was a far cry from that of the great ladies of the Northern Sung or of Chao Tzu-chen. It probably reflects the humble circumstances of her own family as much as her husband's, but that is just the point. In the Southern Sung most clan families had declined to modest, though still elite, status and had privileges, but generally not the influence, that followed from


159

close ties to the emperor and court. For clanswomen to prosper in these changed circumstances, they would have to adopt the attitudes and life-styles of the literati culture, which was coming into its own during the Sung. Although many, perhaps most, of the clanswomen and men may have persisted in their anachronistically aristocratic ways—thus their bad reputation—these women and their biographers pointed the way to the future and in so doing provided a resolution for the tension between the inequalities of rank and gender mentioned above. That the resolution unequivocally affirmed the subordination of women was perhaps only to be expected in a culture in which male achievement was at once essential, yet also in doubt, for their families' fortunes.

Conclusion

In her essay for this volume, Jennifer Holmgren has characterized the Sung as having achieved "a stable and equitable balance of power between the major parties," a balance that contrasts with both the imposing power of the emperor's affinal kin from the Han through T'ang and their powerlessness in the Ming. This finding accords well with the imperial clanswomen considered in these pages. We see on the one hand great dynastic concern for clan marriage relations and a willingness to support the status and honor of the clanswomen through dowries and official titles, even when their relationship to the throne was no longer a mourning one. On the other hand, we see an insistence that they conform to the Confucian norms of filial obedience to their husbands and in-laws, despite their high status.

The most remarkable feature of the Sung clanswomen, however, is to be found, not in balance, but in change. The imperial princesses of the eleventh century were a world apart from the literati-wife clanswomen of the thirteenth. The reasons for this change were numerous. The maturation and social leveling of the imperial clan over time meant that clan members were increasingly likely to be related to the emperor only distantly. This trend was accentuated by the relative infertility of the Southern Sung emperors, which reduced the numbers of close kin. The fall of the Northern Sung gave those clansmen who managed to survive the turmoils of the Jurchen invasion and escape to the south an unprecedented access to government posts. Their families thus had an entrée into local elite society that would otherwise have been unthinkable. Moreover, the shift in the imperial marriage pool from the military elite to the scholar-official bureaucratic elite further decreased the social distance between the imperial clan and local, predominantly literati, elite society.

This essay has not addressed the issue of the declining status of women during the Sung (see, for example, Yao 1983:75-104) and whether it was responsible for the subservience that characterized the exemplary clans-


160

women treated here. One reason for this omission is that there is considerable debate over just how much of a decline actually occurred during the Sung. A great deal of evidence suggests they were much better off than they were to be in the Ming and Ch'ing dynasties in their legal status, marriage practices, and the popularity of widow remarriage and foot binding (see Ebrey 1981, 1984b, and her essay in this volume). The most compelling argument for the decline thesis is that, with the fall of the aristocratic social order of the Six Dynasties-T'ang period and the rise of an examination-centered elite society during the Sung, in which male achievement was considered as essential to the maintenance of the patrilineal kinship group, the woman's roles of servant, nurturer, and loyal supporter of the patriline, even in widowhood, received renewed emphasis, especially by the neo-Confucian thinkers.

The general decline in status for women is not necessarily connected to the roles of the married imperial clanswomen. Ellen Soullière has shown for the Ming, when the subordination of women was certainly more marked than in the Sung, that the husbands of imperial princesses were deliberately drawn from inconsequential families and that they were expected to be ritually and behaviorally subordinate to the wives. Gender, however important, clearly took second place to the dynasty's determination to minimize the potential power of the affinal kin.

Because elite families commonly provided husbands for both princesses and clanswomen, the question of hypogamy vs. gender was a live issue during the Sung, particularly for the clanswomen for whom the hypogamy was not so marked. That their circumstances were necessarily more humble than those of their Northern Sung predecessors was a result of changes in the imperial clan; that their new ideal was that of the uncomplaining, self-sacrificing literati wife can be seen to reflect changes in the gender roles of elite society at large.

Appendix: Princesses and Clanswomen Cited

1. An-k'ang commandery lady

figure
(1168-1205), married Lo Liang-ch'en
figure
. (SS 248:8789)

2.An-te imperial lady

figure
, daughter of Hui-tsung, married Sung Pang-kuang
figure
. (SS 248:8783)

3. Lady Chao (1009-68), commandery lady, married Hsiang Ch'uan-fan

figure
(1010-74) of K'ai-feng. (YCC 21:16a-18a)

4. Lady Chao (fl. 1060), titled Yen-kuo great senior princess

figure
and later Ch'en-kuo great senior princess
figure
, daughter of Jen-tsung, married Li Wei
figure
of K'ai-feng. (SMCTI 33:2b-8a; SS 248:8776-77)

5. Lady Chao (fl. 1094), titled T'ang-kuo senior imperial princess

figure
, married Han Chia-yen
figure
of An-yang hsien


161

figure
, Hsiang-chou
figure
(Ho-pei-hsi). (SMCTI 33:8b-10b; SS 248:8780)

6. Lady Chao (1091-1116) of Ju-chou

figure
(Ching-hsi-pei), married Hao Chen
figure
of Lo-yang
figure
(Wu Su, "Tsu-ch'i Chao-shih muchih," in MLCM 6:47a)

7. Chao Tzu-chen

figure
(1097-1140), titled Yang-kuo fu-jen
figure
, married Yang Ts'un-chung
figure
(1102-22) of Tai-chou
figure
(Ho-tung-lu). (HCCSC 41:la-6b).

8. Lady Chao (1121-58), second wife of Hung Shou-ch'ing

figure
of Jao-chou
figure
(Chiang-nan-hsi). (PCWC 75:8b-6b)

9. Lady Chao (d. 1170), titled proper lady, married Kuan Chien

figure
of Fu-chou
figure
(Chiang-nan-hsi). (ECHC 4:5b-6b)

10. Lady Chao (1153-90), married Wang Fu

figure
of Chi-chou
figure
(Chiang-nan-hsi). (CCC 129:10b-12a)

11. Lady Chao (twelfth century), married Hsu Shih

figure
of Wu-chou
figure
(Liang-che-tung). (CLC 29:431)

12. Lady Chao (1158-1213), titled peaceful lady, married Yuan Jen

figure
of Ming-chou
figure
(Liang-che-tung). (HCC 21:17a)

13. Chao Ju-i

figure
(1183-1221) of Ch'ih-chou
figure
(Chiang-nantung), titled child nurturess, married Wang Meng-lung
figure
(1208 chin-shih ) of T'ai-chou
figure
(Liang-che-tung). (SHWC 25:11a-12a)

14. Chao Hsi-i

figure
(1177-1235) of T'ai-chou
figure
(Liang-che-tung), titled proper lady, married Yuan Fu
figure
of Ming-chou
figure
(Liang-che-tung). (MCC 18:256-57)

15. Chao Ju-chieh

figure
(1199-1249) of Ch'üan-chou
figure
(Fu-chien), titled peaceful lady, married Ch'en Tseng
figure
(1200-1266) of Hsing-hua chün
figure
(Fu-chien). (HTHSTCC 154:4b-5b)

16. Chao Pi-shan

figure
(1188-1260) of Ch'üan-chou
figure
(Fu-chien), titled child nurturess, married Fang Ta-yü
figure
(1181-1234) of Hsing-hua chün
figure
(Fu-chien). (HTHSTCC 158:13b-15a)

17. Chao Shan-i

figure
(1216-43) of Ch'üan-chou
figure
(Fu-chien), titled child nurturess, married Ch'iu Shuang
figure
of Ch'üan-chou. (HTHSTCC 150:17b-19a)

18. Chao Ch'ung-yü

figure
(1206-58), titled child nurturess, married Lo Chin
figure
(1196-1266) of Hung-chou
figure
(Chiang-nan-hsi). (HTHSTCC 158:9a-10b)

19. Ch'en-kuo princess

figure
(d. 1117), Che-tsung's daughter, married Shih Tuan-li. (SS 248:8781)

20. Ch'en-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 999), T'ai-tsu's daughter, married Wei Hsien-hsin
figure
(946-1014) of Wei-chou
figure
(Ho-pei-hsi). (SS 248:8772-73)

21. Ch'eng-te imperial lady

figure
, Hui-tsung's daughter, married Hsiang Tzu-fang
figure
. (SS 248:8785)


162

22. Chia-te imperial lady

figure
, Hui-tsung's daughter, married Tseng Yin
figure
. (SS 248:8783)

23. Ch'in Lu-kuo Hsien-mu Ming-i great senior princess

figure
(1048-1133), Jen-tsung's daughter, married Ch'ien Ching-chen
figure
of Hang-chou
figure
, (Liang-che-hsi). (SS 248:8777)

24. Ch'in-kuo K'ang-i senior princess

figure
(d. 1164), Che-tsung's daughter, married P'an Cheng-fu
figure
of Ho-nan. (SS 248:8782)

25. Ch'in-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 973), T'ai-tsu's younger sister, married first Mi Fu-te
figure
, then Kao Huai-te
figure
(926-82) of Chen-ting fu
figure
(Ho-pei-hsi). (SS 248:8771-72)

26. Ching-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 1051), T'ai-tsung's daughter, married Li Tsun-hsü
figure
(988-1038) of Lu-chou
figure
(Ho-tung). (SS 248:8774-75)

27. Chou-han princess

figure
(1240-61), Li-tsung's daughter, married Yang Chen
figure
of Yen-ling
figure
. (SS 248:8789-90)

28. Ch'ung-te

figure
imperial lady (d. 1120), Hui-tsung's daughter, married Ts'ao Shih
figure
of Chen-ting fu
figure
(Ho-pei-hsi). (SS 248:8784)

29. Han Wei-kuo great senior princess

figure
, Ying-tsung's daughter, married Chang Tun-li
figure
of K'ai-feng. (SS 248:8780)

30. Hsien-te

figure
imperial lady, Hui-tsung's daughter, married Liu Wen-yen
figure
. (SS 248:8785)

31. Hsu-kuo senior princess

figure
(d. 1122), Shen-tsung's daughter, married P'an I
figure
of Ta-ming fu
figure
(Ho-pei-tung). (SS 248:8781)
32. Hsu-kuo great senior princess
figure
(d. 990), T'ai-tsung's daughter, married Wu Yuan-i
figure
(962-1011) of T'ai-yuan fu
figure
(Ho-tung). (SS 248:8773)

33. Hsün-te imperial lady

figure
, Hui-tsung's daughter, married. T'ien P'i
figure
. (SS 248:8785)

34. Ju-fu imperial lady

figure
(d. 1141), Hui-tsung's daughter, married Hsu Huan
figure
. (SS 248:8785)

35. Jung-te imperial lady

figure
, Hui-tsung's daughter, married Ts'ao Sheng
figure
. (SS 248:8783)

36. Lu-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 1009), T'ai-tsu's daughter, married Shih Pao-chi
figure
(954-1010) of K'ai-feng. (SS 248:8772)

37. Mao-te imperial lady

figure
, Hui-tsung's daughter, married Ts'ai T'iao
figure
of Hsing-hua chün
figure
(Fu-chien). (SS 248:8783)

38. Shun-te imperial lady

figure
, Hui-tsung's daughter, married Hsiang Tzu-i
figure
. (SS 248:8785)


163

39. T'an-kuo Hsien-hsiao senior princess

figure
(d. 1108), Shen-tsung's daughter, married Wang Yü
figure
. (SS 248:8781)

40. Wei Ch'u-kuo

figure
great senior princess (d. 1085), Ying-tsung's daughter, married Wang Shih-yueh
figure
(1044-1102) of Lo-yang
figure
(Ho-nan). (SS 8779)

41. Wei-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 1008), T'ai-tsu's daughter, married Wang Ch'eng-yen
figure
of Liao-hsi
figure
, then Lo-yang
figure
. (SS 248:8772)

42. Wei-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 1080), Ying-tsung's daughter, married Wang Shen
figure
of T'ai-yuan fu
figure
(Ho-tung). (SS 248:8779-80)

43. Yang-kuo

figure
great senior princess (d. 1033), T'ai-tsung's daughter, married Ch'ai Tsung-ch'ing
figure
of Ta-ming fu
figure
(Ho-pei-tung). (SS 248:8773-74)

44. Yen Shu-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 1112), Jen-tsung's daughter, married Kuo Hsien-ch'ing
figure
. (SS 248:8778)

45. Yen-kuo great senior princess

figure
(d. 1083), Jen-tsung's daughter, married Ts'ao Shih
figure
of Chen-ting fu
figure
(Ho-pei-hsi). (SS 248:8778)

46. Yung-kuo great senior princess

figure
, T'ai-tsung's daughter, married Wang I-yung
figure
of T'ai-yuan fu
figure
(Ho-tung). (SS 248:8774)

Glossary

an-jeninline image

Chang-i huang-hou (Chang-i empress) inline image

Chao inline image

Chao Chiung inline image

Chao K'uang-yin inline image

Chao Shen inline image

Chao shih (Lady Chao) inline image

Chao T'ing-mei inline image

Che-tsung inline image

Ch'en Chün-ch'ing inline image

Ch'en shih (Lady Ch'en) inline image

Ch'eng I inline image

Ch'eng-chieh-langinline image

Ch'eng-hsin-langinline image

chi-shihinline image

Ch'i-chou inline image

chia-tiinline image

chianginline image

Chiang-nan inline image

Chiang-nan-tung inline image

Chiang-shih-lang inline image

chieninline image

Ch'ien shih (Lady Ch'ien)inline image

chin-shihinline image

ch'inginline image

chiu-liinline image

Chou Pi-ta inline image

chu-weninline image

chü-jeninline image

chüaninline image

Ch'üan-chou inline image

chün-chuinline image

fang-langinline image

Fang Ta-ts'ung inline image

fei shih-tsu chih chiainline image

fei t'an-mien nü i shu-hsing chih fainline image

fenginline image

Fu-chien inline image

Fu-chou (Fu-chien) inline image

fu-ma tu-weiinline image

fu-muinline image

Han Ch'i inline image

Han Chung-yen inline image

Han Wei-kuo ta-chang kung-chu (Han Wei-kuo great senior princess) inline image

Hang-chou inline image

Hao Chen inline image

Ho-nan inline image

Ho-pei-hsi inline image

Ho-pei-tung inline image

Ho-tung inline image

hsi-ch'ininline image

Hsiang Min-chung inline image

Hsiao-tsung inline image

hsien-chuinline image

Hsien-yüan lei-p'u inline image

hsing-t'u-jen inline image

Hsu Chieh-ch'ing inline image

Hsu Huan inline image

hsuaninline image

Hsun-te ti-i (Hsun-te imperial lady) inline image

Huai-nan-hsi inline image

Hui-tsung inline image

Hung-chou inline image

i-chuanginline image

i-jeninline image


166

i-kuan shih-tsuinline image

I-kuo kung-chu (I-kuo princess) inline image

Jen-tsung inline image

ju-jeninline image

ju-muinline image

K'ai-feng inline image

Kao-tsung inline image

kuaninline image

kuan-huinline image

kung-chuinline image

kung-jeninline image

kuo-fu-jeninline image

kuo-iinline image

kuo-t'iinline image

Lang-chou inline image

Lao-tzu inline image

li-chiaoinline image

Li Shou inline image

Li-tsung inline image

lianginline image

Liang-che-hsi inline image

Liang-che-tung inline image

Liang-ching Tsung-cheng-ssu inline image

Liang Huai-chi inline image

Liao-hsi inline image

lien-chüinline image

Lin-an inline image

Lin-ch'uan inline image

ling-jeninline image

Liu Ch'iang-fu inline image

Liu Shu inline image

Lo-yang inline image

Lu-kuo ta-chang kung-chu (Lu-kuo great senior princess) inline image

Lu-ling inline image

Nan-pan-kuaninline image

nei-ch'eninline image

onkeishugiinline image

pai-shen-jeninline image

Pan I inline image

Pao Cheng inline image

P'eng Ju-li inline image

pan-ts'aiinline image

Po Chi inline image

pu hsiang-aninline image

P'u-t'ien inline image

P'u-wang (prince of P'u) inline image

san-pan feng-chihinline image

Shao-hsing fu inline image

Shen-tsung inline image

shihinline image

shih-jeninline image

shih-tsuinline image

shih-ta-fuinline image

Shih Tuan-li inline image

shu-jeninline image

so-t'ing-shihinline image

Ssu-ch'uan inline image

Ssu-ma Kuang inline image

Su Hsun inline image

suiinline image

Sun Ti inline image

ta-erhinline image

Ta-tsung-cheng-ssu inline image

Ta-t'ung inline image

Ta-t'ung Chang inline image

T'ai-tsu inline image

T'ai-tsung inline image

t'an-mieninline image

Tien-chih inline image

T'ien-chihinline image

T'ien-sheng inline image

Ts'ai Ching inline image

Ts'ao-kuo kung-chu (Ts'ao-kuo princess) inline image

Ts'ao Shih inline image

tsunginline image

Tsung-cheng-ssu inline image

tsung-shihinline image

Tun-tsung yuan inline image

tzu-chiinline image

wai-kuaninline image

Wang An-shih inline image

Wang Shen-ch'i inline image

Wang Yü inline image

wei-hsien wei-chia tsung-nüinline image

Wei-wang (prince of Wei) inline image

wu te yü fei shih-tsu chih chia wei hun-yininline image


167

Wu-yueh inline image

Yang-kuo ta-chang kung-chu (Yang-kuo great senior princess) inline image

Yang shih (Lady Yang) inline image

yininline image

Yin-hsien inline image

Ying-tsung inline image

Ying-t'ien fu inline image

Yü-tieh-soinline image

Yuan Hsieh inline image

yuan-sun-n ü inline image

yung-yeh t'ien inline image

References

Primary Sources

CCC Ch'eng-chai chiinline image, by Yang Wan-li inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

CLC Ch'en Liang chiinline image, by Ch'en Liang inline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, n.d.

CWCKCC Chen Wen-chung kung ch'üan-chiinline image, by Chen Te-hsiu inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

CYTC Chien-yen i-lai ch'ao-yeh tsa-chiinline image, 2 parts, by Li Hsin-ch'uan inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

ECHC E-chou hsiao-chiinline image, by Lo Yuan inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'uan-shu edition.

HCC Hsieh-chai chiinline image, by Yuan Hsieh inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

HCCSC Hung-ch'ing chü-shih chiinline image, by Sun Ti inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'uan-shu edition.

HCP Hsu Tzu-chih t'ung-chien ch'ang-pieninline image, by Li T'ao inline image. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1967.

HCPSP Hsu Tzu-chih t'ung-chien ch'ang-pien shih-puinline image, ed. Ch'in Hsiang-yeh inline image. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1967.

HTHSTCC Hou-ts'un hsien-sheng ta ch'üan chiinline image, by Liu K'o-chuang inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

JCSP Jung-chai san-piinline image, by Hung Mai inline image. Pi-chi hsiao-shuo edition.

MCC Meng-chai chiinline image, by Yuan Fu inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

MLCM Mang-lo chung-mu i-wen ssu-pieninline image, by Lo Chen-yü inline image. Shih-k'o shih-liao hsin-pieninline image, no. 19; published by Hsin-wen feng ch'u-pan-she.

OYWCKWC Ou-yang Wen-chung kung wen-chiinline image, by Ou-yang Hsiu inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

PCKT P'ing-chou k'o-t'aninline image, by Chu Yü inline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition.

PCWC P'an-chou wen-chiinline image, by Hung Kua inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.

SHWC Shui-hsin wen-chiinline image, by Yeh Shih inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition.


168

SHY:CK Sung hui-yao chi-kaoinline image, Chih-kuaninline image section. Taipei: Shih-chieh shu-chü, 1964.

SHY:TH Sung hui-yao chi-kao, Ti-hsiinline image section.

SMCTI Sung ming-ch'en tsou-iinline image, by Chao Ju-yü inline image. Ssu-pu ts'ung-k'an edition (This work was originally titled Kuo-ch'ao chu-ch'en tsou-iinline image and was compiled in 1186.)

SS Sung shihinline image, ed. T'o T'o inline image et al. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1977.

STCLC Sung ta-chao ling-chiinline image. Peking: Chung-hua shu-chü, 1962.

TAC T'ieh-an chiinline image, by Fang Ta-ts'ung inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu edition.

WHTK Wen-hsien t'ung-k'aoinline image, by Ma Tuan-lin inline image. Taipei: Hsin-hsing shu-chü, 1964.

YCC Yun-ch'i chiinline image, by Cheng Hsieh inline image. Ssu-k'u ch'üan-shu edition.

Secondary Works

Aoyama Sadao inline image. 1968. Sojindenki sakuininline image (Sung biographical index). Tokyo: Toyo Bunko.

Chaffee, John W. 1985. The Thorny Gates of Learning in Sung China: A Social History of Examinations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ch'ang Pi-te inline image, Wang Te-i inline image, Ch'eng Yuan-min inline image, and Hou Chün-te inline image. 1974-76. Sung-jen chuan-chi tzu-liao so-yininline image (Index to biographical sources for Sung figures). Taipei: Ting-wen shu-chü.

Chung, Priscilla Ching. 1981. Palace Women in the Northern Sung, 960-1126 . Leiden: E.J. Brill.

Comaroff, J. L. 1980. "Introduction." In The Meaning of Marriage Payments , ed. J. L. Comaroff. London: Academic Press.

Duby, Georges 1978. Medieval Marriage: Two Models from Twelfth-Century France Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Ebrey, Patricia. 1978. The Aristocratic Families of Early Imperial China: A Case Study of the Po-ling Ts'ui Family . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

—. 1981. "Women in the Kinship System of the Southern Song Upper Class." Historical Reflections 8:113-28.

—. 1984a. "Conceptions of the Family in the Sung Dynasty." Journal of Asian Studies 43:219-45.

—. 1984b. Family and Property in Sung China: Yüan Ts'ai's Precepts for Social Life . Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Hartwell, Robert M. 1982. "Demographic, Political, Social Transformations of China, 750-1550." Harvard Journal of Asiatic Studies 42:365-442.

Hung Yeh inline image, ed. 1937. Ch'un-ch'iu ching-chuan yin-teinline image (Combined concordance to the Spring and Autumn Annals and commentaries), vol. 1. Peking: Yen-ching University Library.

Hymes, Robert P. 1986. "Marriage, Descent Groups and the Localist Strategy in Sung and Yuan Fu-chou." In Kinship Organization in Late Imperial China , ed. Patricia Buckley Ebrey and James L. Watson·Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.


169

Johnson, David. 1977. The Medieval Chinese Oligarchy . Boulder: Westview Press.

Legge, James, trans. Reprint 1960. The She King . In The Chinese Classics , vol. 4. Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press.

Moroto Tatsuo inline image. "Sodai no tai soshitsu-sakuinline image ni tsuite" inline image (Policies toward the Sung imperial clan). Bungaku 22:623-40.

Soullière, Ellen F. 1988. "The Imperial Marriages of the Ming Dynasty." Papers in Far Eastern History 37:15-42.

Yao, Esther S. Lee. 1983. Chinese Women: Past and Present . Mesquite, Tx.: Ide House.


170

Five
Ch'ing Imperial Marriage and Problems of Rulership

Evelyn S. Rawski

The marriage patterns of the Ch'ing emperors who ruled China from 1644 to 1911 were fundamentally shaped by rulership strategies that influenced the stratification system in several distinctive ways. By limiting marital alliances to the elite of the Manchu, Mongol, and Chinese banner forces, the Ch'ing created a form of political endogamy that excluded ties between the ruling house and the Han Chinese bureaucrats. Imperial marriage patterns were closely tied to Ch'ing succession practices, which rejected eldest-son succession and delayed designation of the heir-apparent until the death of the emperor. This policy stimulated competition among the emperor's sons, weakened the position of the empress, who was not necessarily the most powerful of the emperor's consorts,[1] and minimized status differences between the wife (empress) and concubines. The fluidity of the actual power hierarchy among an emperor's consorts was reflected in the ritual and other privileges held by imperial concubines and in their social origins, which were frequently as elevated as those of empresses. The Ch'ing succession policy helped to support a marriage model that deviated significantly from the one found among commoners.

The Manchus who conquered China in the seventeenth century were descended from the Jurchen, a tribal people living in northeast Asia.[2] In the late fifteenth and early sixteenth centuries, Nurgaci (1559-1626), a petty chieftain, and his son Hung Taiji (1592-1643) united the loosely organized Jurchen tribes to create the Manchu confederation. They formed alliances with Mongol tribes and Chinese transfrontiersmen and organized their Manchu, Mongol, and Han allies into disciplined units, called "banners," to fight against the Ming state. These multiethnic banner forces were the key to the Manchu conquest of China and the establishment of the Ch'ing dynasty.

A conquest dynasty, the Ch'ing confronted major problems in controlling


171

a Chinese population that outnumbered them forty-nine to one. While maintaining military primacy, the first rulers won over the Chinese literati by adopting the Confucian framework for government. Ch'ing emperors learned Chinese, patronized Chinese art and scholarship, issued hortatory edicts supporting Confucian values, continued the sacrifices in the state religion, and performed Chinese rituals at marriage and death. But, like the other non-Han dynasties analyzed by Jennifer Holmgren in this volume, the Manchus did not adopt the entire Chinese model. Their marriage system was substantially influenced by the political conditions they faced.

Like earlier non-Han dynasties, the Ch'ing used marriage exchange as an important tool for foreign alliances, both during and after the crucial conquest period. The stable circle of marriage partners for the Ch'ing ruling family was confined to the conquest elite and their peers in the steppe society. The multiethnic makeup of the victorious banner forces and the imperative need to maintain military supremacy shaped the policy allowing Manchus to marry Manchu, Mongol, or Chinese bannermen, but not Chinese in the civilian population.

One of the key problems of rulership—succession—heavily influenced Ch'ing marriage. Although the Manchus gradually shifted from their tribal custom of rule by council to one-man rule and father-son succession during the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries,[3] they did not adopt the succession customs of the Ming dynasty (1368-1644). The Ming, a Han Chinese ruling house, publicly installed the empress's first son as heir-apparent while he was still a child; if the empress were barren, the eldest son inherited the throne. In eleven of the fifteen cases of imperial succession in the Ming, a first son inherited the throne from his father. By contrast, there was only one instance, in the nineteenth century, of an empress's son actually mounting the Ch'ing throne, and two other instances, that same century, of the throne passing to the eldest son (table 5.1).[4]

The Ch'ing rejection of eldest-son succession was initially dictated by political struggles accompanying the emergence of one-man rule. The group leadership that seems to have been intended by Nurgaci broke down when his eighth son, Hung Taiji, became the undisputed supreme leader after his father's death. When Hung Taiji died in 1643, his brother Dorgon dominated the government as regent by selecting Hung Taiji's ninth son, an infant, to succeed over his older brothers. The next heir, chosen in 1661 as the emperor lay dying of smallpox, was preferred over an older brother partly because he had already had the disease.[5] The K'ang-hsi emperor did install his first son by the empress as heir, but found his heir-apparent grievously unfit for office and demoted him. By the early eighteenth century the Ch'ing rulers had substituted a system of secret succession in place of the Ming custom. The emperor would seal the name of his choice in a coffer to be opened only upon his death (Huang 1974:95-96).


172

TABLE 5.1
The Manchu Imperial Succession


Emperor


Reign Period


Birth Order a


Eldest Son

Mother's Rank b

Shun-chih

1644-61

9

 

C4

K'ang-hsi

1661-1722

3

 

C4

Yung-cheng

1722-35

4

 

C4

Ch'ien-lung

1735-95

5

 

C3

Chia-ch'ing

1796-1820

15

 

C2

Tao-kuang

1820-50

2

x

C1

Hsien-feng

1850-61

4

x

C1c

T'ung-chih

1861-74

1

x

C2

Kuang-hsu

1874-1908

d

 

?

Hsuan-t'ung

1908-11

e

 

?

a Among sons only.

b Highest rank attained during her husband's lifetime: C1 = empress, C2 = huang-kuei-fei , C3 = kuei-fei , C4 = fei .

c Entered as fourth-ranking concubine; promoted once son became emperor.

d The son of T'ung-chih's father's younger brother, or T'ung-chih's cousin.

e The son of Kuang-hsu's younger brother, or Kuang-hsu's nephew.

The Ch'ing rejection of the eldest-son succession principle, coupled with the secret and delayed designation of the heir, produced intense succession struggles. The contest for succession—which one scholar (Fletcher 1979) has likened to the "bloody tanistry" of successions in the Ottoman Empire—divided brother from brother, with the victor exterminating his rivals. To this day scholars write about the "usurpation" of the Yung-cheng emperor, who is said to have forged his father's will. It is perhaps no accident that this emperor was one of the most ruthless rulers in the history of the dynasty.

The Ch'ing abandonment of eldest-son succession was a destabilizing force on the imperial family. With succession a wide-open competition whose outcome was determined only on an emperor's deathbed, there could be no spatial and social separation of the heir from his siblings, as occurred in the Ming (for discussion of different succession regimes in Chinese history see Holmgren's chapter in this volume). There could be no discrimination in the education or marriage of one son as opposed to another, and sons were not barred from political participation. Unlike the Ming, which sought to exclude imperial agnates from governance, the Ch'ing emperor's sons, grandsons, and other agnates were assigned to carry out ritual, military, and diplomatic tasks, with their fitness for the throne evaluated by their performance.

The commoner norm dictating that sons of concubines ritually and legally regard the first wife (here the empress) as mother was not fully followed in the Ch'ing palace. Although an emperor had only one empress at a time, he could be survived by several empresses dowager because the first act of most


173

Ch'ing emperors was to promote their natural mothers to this status. As the mother of the emperor, such a woman could wield enormous power at court, greater than that of the empress: the most notorious example is Empress Dowager Tz'u-hsi, who easily manipulated her nominal superior Empress Tz'u-an to dominate Ch'ing politics from the 1860s until her death in 1908. Although the Ch'ing did not have a truly polygynous system of marriage, we shall argue that the system of imperial concubinage was distinctive, being neither strictly monogamous nor polygamous. In the Ch'ing imperial system, concubines enjoyed access to the ritual, legal, and social privileges accorded to the first wife or empress. Status differences among the consorts of an emperor were differences of degree, not of kind.

The sources for studying Ch'ing imperial marriage patterns are exceptionally rich. The ritual procedures are described in detail in the Ta Ch'ing hui-tien (Administrative Regulations of the Ch'ing Dynasty); the Ch'in-ting ta-Ch'ing t'ung-li (Comprehensive Rituals of the Ch'ing), produced in the eighteenth century; and in archival documents held by the Number One Historical Archives in Peking. These archival materials indicate that those planning the weddings of the T'ung-chih and Kuang-hsu emperors in the nineteenth century relied heavily on the hui-tien (KCTC no. 2379; P. Li 1983:80). The marriage partners (including concubines) of the imperial line are recorded in the genealogy of the Ch'ing imperial house, printed in the twentieth century, which is supplemented by the more comprehensive manuscript copy (Ta Ch'ing yü-tieh ). The Number One Historical Archives also has abundant supplementary documentation on the personnel of the Inner Quarters in the records of the Imperial Household Department.

The emperor was the head of the Aisin Gioro lineage,[6] which was regulated by the Imperial Clan Court (tsung-jen fu ). All marriages (along with births and deaths) were recorded in the imperial genealogy (Ta Ch'ing yü-tieh ), which was periodically revised (TJFTL , 1.10a). Moreover, the marriages of all members of the main line (tsung-shih , consisting of the descendants of Taksi, the great-grandfather of the first Ch'ing emperor, Shun-chih), initially required the emperor's approval (TCHTSL , c. 1; TJFTL , 2. la-9b). In the course of the dynasty, the growth of the lineage forced emperors to narrow the circle of kin whose marriages they arranged.[7] But even in the late nineteenth century the emperor retained the right to select brides for the sons of princes in his father's and his own generation, and grooms for the daughters of princes of the first six ranks (for the Sung, see Chaffee's chapter in this volume). In this paper, however, I focus on a much smaller subgroup; namely, the sons and daughters of emperors, and emperors themselves.

The Influence of Manchu Customs

Like the Mongols (Holmgren 1986:144-45), the Jurchens seem to have had a tradition of marriage by seizure (S. Yang 1984; Shirokogoroff 1973) and to


174

have practiced clan exogamy,[8] but they placed no restrictions on cross-generational marriage. Hung Taiji's empress, Hsiao-tuan, was joined in the emperor's harem by her two nieces. Shun-chih's (1638-61) second empress was a first collateral niece of his first empress, whom he had deposed in 1653. Imperial unions continued to disregard the generational principle into the nineteenth century, when one of the T'ung-chih (1856-75) emperor's concubines was the paternal aunt of his empress.

Worse (from the Chinese perspective), Manchu society originally practiced the levirate; that is, men were encouraged to marry their brothers' widows, sons to marry their father's widows (but never their birth mothers), and nephews the widows of their paternal uncles (Tao 1976:12; H. Li 1985). One assumes they practiced the levirate for the same reasons Mongols did: to maintain "the viability of the family patrimony" by keeping widows from leaving and taking their property with them (Holmgren 1986:153). Among Han Chinese, the senior levirate (marriage with an older brother's wife) was treated as incest. Some poor Chinese practiced the junior levirate, but from T'ang times at least such marriages were legally prohibited, punishable by strangulation, and according to Feng, "even in the few places where it is practiced, it is not considered respectable" (1967:51).

In 1631 and 1636 Hung Taiji publicly banned the senior levirate, along with marrying a father's widow and the widows of a father's brothers, as part of the Manchu adoption of Han Chinese customs. The new marriage rules were not always obeyed. Princess Mukushih, fourth daughter of Nurgaci, was divorced from her first husband, then married to Eidu, the famous hero of the Niohuru clan.[9] After Eidu's death, Mukushih married Turgei, his son by another woman (Li Feng-min 1984; Huang 1986:638). Although one scholar (Li Feng-min 1984) asserts that the couple was punished for this transgression, we should note that Mukushih lived to the ripe age of sixty-five, and Turgei, "highly regarded" by Hung Taiji (Hummel 1943 1:222), was rewarded for his military prowess after his marriage to Mukushih.

The Manchu rulers continued to observe Han Chinese generational rules with laxity, but in other respects their marriages came to comply with Chinese taboos. The marriage of a widow to her former husband's son or to her husband's brother is not found after 1648 in the imperial genealogy. Marriage to sisters, which was consonant with Chinese and Mongol traditions, was practiced by Manchu rulers (Feng 1967:46-48; Holmgren 1986:142-43). Hung, Taiji K'ang-hsi (1654-1722), and Hsien-feng (1831-61) all had sisters in their harems (K'ang-hsi had four sororal pairs), and the Kuang-hsu emperor (1871-1908) took two sisters as concubines when he married his empress in 1888.

Matrilateral cross-cousin marriages (marrying the mother's brother's daughter), practiced in some parts of China (Gallin 1963), was also favored by the Mongols (Krader 1963:24) and practiced by the Manchu rulers.


175

K'ang-hsi and Kuang-hsu both had concubines who were related to them in this way, and Nurgaci married at least two of his daughters to his sisters' sons.[10]

As in other non-Han dynasties (see Holmgren's chapter in this volume), after 1655 all Manchus were forbidden to marry Han Chinese who were not enrolled in the Eight Banners (Wang Tao-ch'eng 1985a:305-6; P'u 1982: 124). This prohibition was spelled out in the regulations of the Imperial Clan Court (TJFTL 31.19ab); those who disobeyed were punished, and any offspring expelled from the lineage. As we shall see, this rule, which permitted marriage within a group of long-term political followers, constituted a form of political endogamy.

Marriage and Politics

In the critical years before 1683, when the Manchu rulers were creating their empire, marriage exchanges functioned as an important means of winning new allies and stabilizing military coalitions. Rival Manchu tribal leaders, Mongol princes, Chinese frontiersmen, and Chinese generals were rewarded for their support with Aisin Gioro wives and enrolled in the Manchu, Mongol, and Chinese banners created during the early seventeenth century.

The banners were large civil-military units created in the early seventeenth century that replaced the small hunting groups of Nurgaci's early campaigns. Composed of companies, each with three hundred households of warriors and headed by a hereditary leader (Wakeman 1985:54-55), the banners became administrative units for registration, conscription, taxation, and mobilization of the tribes and peoples who joined the Manchu cause before 1644. To the eight Manchu banners were added, by 1635, eight Mongol (Ch'en 1984:114) and by 1642 eight Chinese banners (Wakeman 1985: 200-201). The conquest of China was achieved by these combined banner forces, in which less than 16 percent of the soldiers by 1648 were actually of Manchu origin (An 1983).

Table 5.2 summarizes the ethnic origins of the principal spouses of emperors, princes, and princesses. For the moment, we will focus only on the first wives of emperors and princes and the marriages of princesses, who were all first wives. Because later marriages followed the patterns begun by Nurgaci and his successor, Hung Taiji, they are included in the table, which ends with the children of the Hsien-feng emperor (1831-61).[11]

Empresses, ti fujin (wives of princes), and efu (husbands of princesses) came from a relatively small number of favored houses (see table 5.2). Of the 641 Manchu clans listed in the Pa-ch'i Man-chou shih-tsu t'ung-p'u compiled in 1745, only 31 were favored by the Aisin Gioro lineage with marriage. Among the Manchu clans, the Niohuru descended from Eidu supplied almost half of the empresses for the entire dynasty. Their bonds with the Aisin Gioro were


176

TABLE 5.2
Preferred Affines of Emperors, Princes, and Princesses

 

Empress a

Princes'
Wives
b

Princesses' Husbandsc

Total No.
of Women

Ethnicity

         

Chinese

0

4

4

8

Manchu

15

47

24

86

Mongol

5

10

35

50

Total no. of women

20

61

63

144

Manchu affines

         

Donggo

0

3

1

4

Fuca

1

5

3

9

Guololo

0

2

1

3

Guwalgiya

0

5

4

9

Irgen Gioro

0

3

2

5

Nara

0

7

4

11

Niohuru

5

4

4

13

Sirin Gioro

0

2

0

2

Tatara

0

2

0

2

Ula Nara

3

0

0

3

Yehe Nara

2

1

0

3

Other clans

4

13

5

22

Total no. of clans

8

23

12

 

SOURCE : TCYT .

a Only empresses given that title during the emperor's lifetime are included. The table begins with Nurgaci and his offspring.

b The "first wife" of a prince.

c The husband of a princess; here only princesses born or adopted by emperors are counted.

exceptionally close. The Niohuru genealogy analyzed by Huang P'ei records seventy-seven of Eidu's male descendants and seventy-two Niohuru daughters marrying into the Aisin Gioro main line (Huang 1986:638). The Manchus also displayed a strong preference for Mongol spouses: 25 percent of empresses, 16 percent of princes' wives, and 55 percent of princesses' husbands were Mongol. The Khorchins, who were the earliest Mongol allies of the Manchus, were especially favored: twelve sons-in-law, an empress, and one prince's wife were Khorchin. There were no Hun Chinese empresses, and the Chinese princely wives and husbands either date from the period of conquest or belonged to the Chinese banners.

Manchu Affines

The favored marriage partners among the Manchu clans were those who had allied themselves with the Aisin Gioro lineage. The exchange of wives had long been an accepted mode of cementing tribal alliances. The Manchus


177

interspersed such alliances with the use of force to unify the Jurchen tribes. Of the Guwalgiya, Niohuru, Sumuru, Nara, Donggo, Hoifa, Ula, Irgen Gioro, and Magiya clans that formed the so-called Eight Great Houses,[12] only the Hoifa is missing from the list of imperial affines presented in table 5.2. "Heroes" of the conquest period were often rewarded with Aisin Gioro brides. Hohori (1561-1624), of the Donggo clan (Hummel 1943 1:291), wed Nurgaci's eldest daughter. Fiongdon (1564-1620), of the Suwan Guwalgiya clan (ibid., 247), distinguished himself in Nurgaci's military campaigns and obtained noble titles and wives for his sons.

Mongol Affines

Manchu marriages with Mongol nobles also increased as the Ch'ing armies expanded into central Asia in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. Earlier Chinese dynasties had given princesses to Mongol princes and other "barbarian" tribal leaders, but the Manchus conducted a bilateral exchange of wives on an unprecedented scale. The frequency of Manchu marriage exchanges with Mongol princes underlines the crucial importance of the Mongols in the Manchu conquest of Ming China.

From 1612 the Manchus wooed the Khorchin Mongols of western Manchuria and Inner Mongolia away from adherence to the Ming. Mongols who "came over" were showered with gifts and presented with Aisin Gioro wives. They in turn wed their daughters to the Manchu rulers. Nurgaci is said to have proclaimed: "The Manchus and Mongols have different speech [languages] but their clothing comes from the same origin, and they are brother states" (Lü 1985:18). Resisting the Chahar Mongol leader Ligdan Khan's attempts (supported by the Ming) to unify the Mongol tribes, the Khorchin allied with the Manchus to defeat Ligdan Khan in 1634. Once defeated, the Chahar Mongols were also wooed by the Manchus, who presented a Manchu princess to Ligdan Khan's heir in 1635. The Qalqa Mongols, who lived further west in what is now Outer Mongolia, were also courted: in 1617, for example, Nurgaci gave one of his nieces to Enggeder, son of a Qalqa khan who came over to the Manchu cause, and accepted another Qalqa prince's daughter as a daughter-in-law. By 1691 the Qalqa Mongols were absorbed into the Manchu state and reorganized into Mongol banners (Bawden 1968; Lattimore 1934).

Ch'ing marriage networks grew with the Manchu penetration of central and north Asia. The Tüshiyetü Khan exercised sovereignty over the Mongol tribes in east-central Outer Mongolia; their primary regional center, Urga (modern-day Ulan Bator), had been captured by Galdan, leader of the Zunghars, in 1688. In 1697, a year after the Ch'ing troops had defeated Galdan, a grandson of the Tüshiyetü Khan married K'ang-hsi's sixth daughter; several years later (1702) an alliance with the Jasaghtu Khan, who ruled over the Mongol tribes further west, was cemented by his marriage to the daughter of


178

a Manchu prince. In 1706 a descendant of the Sayin Noyan Khan, who held the territory between the Jasaghtu and Tüshiyetü Khans, was married to K'ang-hsi's tenth daughter (Bawden 1968).

The Ch'ing subjugation of the Western Mongols was achieved with the aid of their Mongol allies; as Lattimore (1934:60) notes, "Manchu sovereignty was not achieved by outright conquest but was always based on alliance with some one group of Mongols against another group and the status of Mongols within the empire was different from, and higher than, the Chinese." By the nineteenth century the previously mighty Mongol domains were supervised by Ch'ing appointees, the Mongol nobility held Ch'ing titles, the once powerful tribes had been reorganized into banners, and the khans "were little more than distinguished banner princes" (Fletcher 1978:51).

From 1636 onward Mongols were given Manchu titles of nobility. Mongol nobles from 1614 on exchanged daughters and sisters with the Manchu rulers, and were tied to the Aisin Gioro lineage by a complex network of affinal exchanges. Manjusri (1599-1649), a Khorchin Mongol noble, was the nephew of Empress Hsiao-tuan, Hung Taiji's wife. Two of Manjusri's daughters married two of Hung Taiji's sons; in 1636 he was given the title "Baturu chün-wang," designating leadership of one of the six political units into which the Manchus divided the Khorchins. Empress Hsiao-tuan was herself related to four of the six princes who ruled the Khorchins under the Ch'ing (Hummel 1943 1:304). Moreover, her three daughters, and those of her niece, Empress Hsiao-chuang (mother of the Shun-chih emperor), half-Khorchin in descent, were all married to Mongol nobles. Other Mongols also participated in these sustained marriage exchanges. For example, marriage ties between the Aisin Gioro and the descendants of Bandi, son-in-law of Hung Taiji and leader of the Aokhan Mongols, lasted for five generations (Hua 1983:52).

The cultivation of ties extended beyond marriage. From 1659 onward, sons of Manchu princesses could be reared in Peking at court (Chao 1984), and from K'ang-hsi's reign, some Mongol boys of noble descent were invited to Peking, where they were raised in the palace and attended school with the Manchu princes (Hua 1983). The Shang-shu-fang, founded by the Yung-cheng emperor (1678-1735) to educate imperial sons, grandsons, and other princes (including sons-in-law), taught Mongol as well as Manchu and Chinese (Kahn 1971:117-20). When they came of age, these Mongols were married to princesses and frequently served the Ch'ing. Tsereng, the Qalqa noble (Hummel 1944 2:756-57) who married K'ang-hsi's fourth daughter (1706), performed exceptional military service in the Ch'ing campaigns against Galdan and won commemoration in the Ch'ing imperial ancestral temple in Peking. Septen Baljur, a Khorchin noble who married Ch'ien-lung's third daughter, had a similar background (Hua 1983). Many Mongols


179

became an integral part of Ch'ing society: Ch'ung Ch'i, father of T'ung-chih's empress and a member of the Mongol Plain Blue Banner, was the son of a grand councillor and grand secretary, a chuang-yuan in the 1865 chin-shih examinations, and a Ch'ing official (Hummel 1944 1:208-9).

Marriages with Mongols did not end with the stabilization of China's Inner Asian frontiers in the mid-eighteenth century. By this period, the Ch'ien-lung emperor (1711-99) called the pattern of marrying Ch'ing princesses to Mongols a tradition that should be maintained (TCHTSL c. 1), although he also permitted (in 1751) princesses to marry into distinguished banner families (TJFTL 2.6a). Through the nineteenth century, successive emperors tried to preserve this marriage pattern by reiterating that the names of eligible young Mongols (and information on three generations of their forebears) must be sent to the Li fan yuan (Court of Colonial Affairs) for selection as sons-in-law (TCHTSL c.1; TJFTL 2.la; Chao 1984; Hua 1983). The marriages between the Aisin Gioro lineage and the Mongol aristocracy continued into the nineteenth century; by the 1820s-1840s more than three thousand such marriages were recorded (Hua 1983:52). If we ignore the tribal designations, Mongol nobles were the single largest group with whom the imperial house exchanged marriage partners.

Chinese Bannermen

Chinese who came over to the Manchu cause in the years before 1644 were also showered with rank, honors, and Aisin Gioro wives. This policy was clearly expressed in a letter sent by Nurgaci to the commander of the Fu-shun garrison, Li Yung-fang, in 1618 during his first major campaign against the Ming (Wakeman 1985 1:60): "If you submit without fighting . . . I will let you live just as you did before. I will promote . . . the people with great knowledge and foresight . . . give them daughters in marriage and care for them. I will give you a higher position than you have and treat you .like one of my officials of the first degree." Li Yung-fang surrendered the city and was treated "as a Chinese frontiersman admitted into the ranks of the Jin aristocracy" (ibid., 61); he married one of Nurgaci's granddaughters, fought alongside Nurgaci, and died a viscount. His nine sons continued to serve the Manchus and were enrolled in the Chinese Plain Blue Banner after 1642. At least one of them—the second son, Shuai-t'ai—also married into the Aisin Gioro lineage (Hummel 1943 1:499).

Sun Ssu-k'o, the son of a Ming officer who surrendered to Nurgaci in 1622, was enrolled in the Chinese Plain White Banner and helped to lead the Manchu troops in defeating the Eleuths at the battle of Jao Modo (1695); he was rewarded with a title, and his son was married to K'ang-hsi's fourth daughter (ibid. 2:682). Wu San-kuei, Shang K'o-hsi, and Keng Chi-mao, the three Han Chinese generals who were instrumental in the Manchu conquest of


180

south China, were each granted princely titles otherwise reserved only for Manchus and Mongols, and were linked by marriage with the imperial house (TCYT ; Hummel 1943 1:415-16; T'ang 1923:192-93).[13]

These Chinese bannermen—the term derives from the designation (Han-chün ) used in 1642 when the Chinese banners were organized—served the: Manchu rulers as advisers, generals, and officials in the crucial conquest period. Especially in the seventeenth century, their language and cultural knowledge made them favored appointees for local government posts in China. Chinese bannermen dominated the posts of governor and governor-general during the late seventeenth century (Wakeman 1985 2:1021-23, 1024, 1029, 1031-33). Wakeman concludes that the Shun-chih reign "saw the transformation of Han bannermen into a new supra-elite, acting almost like provincial janissaries for the throne," and even replacing Chinese degree holders in posts (ibid., 1020). Like other Manchu adherents, their loyalty and service to the throne frequently continued over many generations (ibid., 1018-20). The T'ungs of Fu-shun, sinicized Jurchen who joined the Manchu cause from 1618 to 1645, are an outstanding example of the rewards, which included promotion into a Manchu banner, heaped upon loyal Chinese bannermen (Crossley 1983; Hou 1982).

Chinese bannermen were sharply distinguished from Chinese captured in the early phases of the Manchu conquest, who became bondservants, a hereditary servile status. Mongol, Korean, and Chinese bondservants were used to till the estates created in north China for imperial kinsmen, banner officials, and bannermen (Wei, Wu, and Lu 1982). Organized according to the Eight Banner system, bondservants in the upper three banners (the Bordered Yellow, the Plain Yellow, and the Plain White) came under the direct personal control of the emperor in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries and were appointed to positions within the Imperial Household Department (Torbert 1977). Their servile status did not prevent some bond-servants from becoming rich and powerful; they were used for delicate and confidential tasks by the emperors, and some attained provincial and even central government posts (Spence 1966:13-15). And, as we shall see, daughters of Chinese bondservants could also enter the imperial harem.

The differentiation between Chinese bannermen and Chinese civilians was primarily a political one, but there is also evidence that "culturally the important distinctions of the early Qing period lay not between the Manchus and the Chinese-martial Bannermen but between the Bannermen of all origins and the conquered Chinese" (Crossley 1987:779). In the early stages the designation of Chinese bannermen had been applied to persons who were not necessarily racially Chinese, but who had been subjects of the Ming (ibid.). Many were in fact northeast Asians who had settled in Liaotung: sinicized Jurchens, Mongols, Koreans were thus called nikan , the Manchu word for persons who lived in the manner of Chinese. In fact, the early Mongol and


181

the Chinese banners both enrolled descendants of Jurchen (ibid.). By the 1660s many Chinese bannermen were second- and third-generation descendants of officers who had joined the Manchu cause and were "barely distinguishable from the Manchu nobility" (Wakeman 1985 2:1017). Many had been "transfrontiersmen" who through long residence in Liaoning had become accustomed to Manchu ways and took on Manchu identity with Nurgaci's acquiescence (ibid., 1:45). Nurgaci classified "individuals on the basis of their culture primarily"; the K'ang-hsi emperor displayed his relaxed attitude toward ethnicity in his willingness to transfer whole Mongol tribes and Chinese lineages from the Mongol and Chinese banners to the Manchu banners (Crossley 1987:779). Indeed, K'ang-hsi's willingness to incorporate other ethnic groups into the banner system extended even to Russian prisoners of war, who were enrolled as a company in the Bordered Yellow Banner in 1685 (Wu 1987).

Support for the argument that the Manchus emphasized political rather than ethnic boundaries in their marriage patterns can be found in analysis of the circumstances surrounding the 1648 decision of the "Imperial Father Regent," Dorgon, to permit Manchu-Han marriages. In 1648 the Manchu conquest of China was far from assured, and Dorgon used various measures to try to obtain the voluntary compliance of Chinese to Manchu rule. Bannermen were prohibited (after 1644) from plundering civilians; from 1647 onward imperial pronouncements repeated the theme that "Manchu and Han are one family." The subject set for the palace examinations in 1649 was how Manchus and Han could be brought to live together (Kessler 1976:15-17; Chou and Chao 1986:408-9). In reality, this policy could not be implemented. Ethnic strife in Peking forced Dorgon to rule (October 5, 1648) that the two races should be separated so that each could "live in peace." The bannermen were eventually housed in separate walled garrison quarters in thirty-four cities across north China (Wakeman 1985 1:480).

The edict ordering the removal of all Chinese from the northern imperial city to the southern city in Peking was followed a day later by an edict permitting intermarriage to promote friendship between Manchus and Han. Details implementing this policy were announced on October 14 (TCSL 40.9ab, Ila, 14ab). In what can be interpreted as an effort to win over the Han populace, the edict specified that Manchus marrying Han women were required to take them as wives and not concubines.

We do not know how many individuals availed themselves of the opportunity offered by the 1648 edict;[14] what we do know is that the policy permitting intermarriage ended abruptly in 1655. Dorgon was dead; the young emperor responded angrily to a memorial from a Chinese official who criticized an expedition to Yangchow to buy Chinese women for the palace. The memorialist, Li K'ai-sheng, touched on the delicate ethnic situation, reminded the emperor that Yangchow had the "bandit spirit" (it had forcibly


182

resisted the Ch'ing armies), and warned of the adverse public reaction to such activities. The emperor, who punished Li for his memorial, indignantly denied the truth of the charges and reiterated the Manchu tradition that excluded Chinese women from the imperial harem (TCSL 92.13b-15b, 20b).

The 1648 edict removing Chinese from the imperial city in Peking specifically exempted Chinese bannermen. Nor were the Manchus alone in thus separating Chinese bannermen from the rest of the Chinese population. Contemporary Han Chinese looked down on them as "racial renegades and no better than Manchus" (Kessler 1976:18) because they had betrayed the Ming cause. The distinction between Chinese bannermen and Han Chinese is clear in a 1651 complaint by a Han Chinese censor, who urged the emperor to stop relying so heavily on bannermen in top provincial posts (ibid., 17-18)—as we have already noted, Chinese bannermen dominated provincial posts during this period.

The early Manchu laxity toward "ethnic purity" was replaced in the mid-eighteenth century by a heightened concern with the maintenance of Manchu separateness. The empire was secured, the frontiers stabilized. The Ch'ien-lung emperor, who saw himself as the ruler of a multicultural empire, desired that "there should be orderly congruence of race to custom"; during his reign, oral genealogies were written down, every Manchu was fixed within a clan, and the major clans were traced back to the Chin dynasty that had ruled north China during the twelfth century. Concern for the preservation of Manchu identity was expressed in strictures on the maintenance of Manchu dress and the perpetuation of shamanism, the traditional Manchu religion. The prohibition against intermarriage with Han Chinese was no doubt strengthened by these new attitudes, and prevailed until the end of the dynasty.

In its emphasis on the military segment of society, Ch'ing imperial marriages greatly resembled those of the Northern Sung (Chung 1981), when virtually none of the imperial concubines came from the prominent scholar-official families. In the Ming, as in the Northern Sung, imperial marriage partners tended to be drawn from hereditary military families (Soullière 1988). Scholar-officials might consider themselves the sine qua non of the dynasty; that the imperial perception differed is suggested by the consistent priority given to wu (the military) over wen (the civilian officials) in imperial marriage.

The Recruitment of Women for Emperors and Princes

The number of acknowledged empresses and concubines varied greatly by emperor, ranging from K'ang-hsi with 40 to Kuang-hsu with only 3. With 9 emperors (excluding the last emperor, P'u-i) claiming a total of 155 wives and concubines, the Ch'ing harems were relatively large.[15] Unlike the T'ang


183

dynasty, with its elaborate structure for the imperial harem (Chung 1981:18-20), the Ch'ing hierarchy, defined in 1636, was relatively simple. Concubines were differentiated into seven ranks: the highest was huang-kuei-fei , then, in descending order, kuei-fei, fei, pin, kuei-jen, ch'ang-tsai , and ta-ying .[16] Rank determined the allotments of food, clothing, jewelry, etc., as well as cash stipends and maids, that a woman received (KCTL c. 3). The highest rank (empress dowager) received 300,000 taels a year (Lu 1982).[17]

The Ch'ing procedure for the selection of imperial and princely consorts was narrower than those of earlier dynasties.[18] The Ch'ing modified the Ming and Northern Sung practice of drafting women from the civilian population for palace service and selecting consorts from the palace maids (Chung 1981:9-11; Shan 1960). Beginning with Shun-chih's second empress in 1653 (Wei 1984:20), brides for the Aisin Gioro line were selected from the triennial draft of hsiu-nü (beautiful women) who were daughters of officials in the banners (TCHTSL c. 1114; HPTL 1.14a-23a). With the exception of specified individuals who became exempt in the course of the dynasty, the emperors enforced the requirement that every eligible girl had to appear in Peking in the draft before her betrothal, beginning from the age of thirteen to fourteen sui .

The hsiu-nü inspection was held in the capital. In Peking, the girls entered the Inner Quarters of the palace grouped by banner (Manchu, Mongol, and Chinese) and within each by age. The emperor and empress who personally inspected the girls to select brides for their sons and imperial agnates were furnished with the particulars of their family backgrounds and birthdates (the latter were used to compare the "eight characters" of the prospective couple); those passing the first draft were inspected by the senior empress dowager, who was provided with the ranks and names of the girl's maternal grandfather and her paternal forebears for three generations. Choices could thus be based not only on a girl's personal appearance but also on her family's status. The Yung-cheng emperor emphasized the latter: he ruled that the selection of empresses and concubines of ranks one through five should be made only from the families of hereditary banner officials above a certain rank (Wang Tao-ch'eng 1985a:306). The notion that father's rank determined that of his daughter in the imperial harem is supported by a blank form from the mid-nineteenth century, which equates a hereditary duke to a fei , a prefect to a pin , and so on (ibid., 311).

Some hsiu-nü were immediately selected as wives or concubines for princes, or for the emperor himself. The empresses of the K'ang-hsi, T'ung-chih, and Kuang-hsu emperors were selected from the hsiu-nü draft (CTKTSH illus. 225, 226, p. 165; Sun 1985:52). Empress Dowager Tz'u-hsi was chosen in the hsiu-nü draft of March 28, 1852, designated a sixth-rank concubine, and introduced into the palace on June 26, 1852 (Yü 1985a:130).

Hsiu-nü who did not enter the imperial or princely harems probably be-


184

came ladies-in-waiting, serving for a five-year term and provided with stipends according to their rank. At the end of five years they were permitted to leave with a grant of twenty taels of silver. These hsiu-nü who caught the emperor's eye could still be promoted into the harem. This seems to have been the way Te fei, one of K'ang-hsi's favorite concubines, entered the palace. Te fei, who produced six children, was "originally a lady-in-waiting from the Uya clan" whose father was an officer in the banners (S. Wu 1979:36).

The other way to enter a princely or imperial household was through the draft for palace maids (kung-nü ), who were selected from the daughters of bondservant officials in the upper three banners who were serving in the Imperial Household Department (Shan 1960; TCHTSL c. 1,218). Palace serving women were occasionally plucked out of the ranks; a not inconsiderable 16 percent of concubines entered the harem through this means.[19] Many were probably from humble backgrounds: in 1700 the emperor ordered that, "since the girls coming to the palace for . . . selection as palace maids were mainly from poor families, they be taken to warm quarters and fed with hot soup and rice when the weather was cold" (Torbert 1977:75).

Unlike the triennial hsiu-nü draft, the recruitment of palace maids took place once a year and was managed by the Imperial Household Department. Girls aged thirteen sui were brought to the palace for inspection and selection by the emperor. Most were assigned to the different palaces to fill the quota of maids assigned to the emperor, empress dowager, empress, and ranked' concubines. Four hundred to five hundred palace maids and eunuchs were said to have staffed the palace during the K'ang-hsi reign; by Tz'u-hsi's time, there were eleven hundred maids alone (Shan 1960:97). Each maid was allocated a daily food ration, and received bolts of silk and cotton. Some received up to six taels of silver a year for their service (Lu 1982). Palace maids could be married off with dowries at age twenty-five if in general service, and at age thirty-five if they served imperial persons (KTCL 3.2a-3a).

In contrast to the lax policies concerning intermarriage with bondservants in the early Ch'ing, regulations preventing their selection as concubines or wives of males in the main line were put in place by the late nineteenth century. The Yung-cheng emperor himself noted in 1727 that the Manchus (unlike the Chinese) observed "strict separation and distinction between master and bondservant" (Torbert 1977:56-57). Intermarriage of regular bannermen and bondservants was forbidden (ibid., 68), and there were stringent rules against Aisin Gioro marrying bondservants from the lower five banners, that is, those banners not directly controlled by the emperor (TJFTL 31.20a-21a).

Imperial consorts of bondservant background, who had probably begun as palace maids, included Ch'ien-lung's third empress, the daughter of a palace overseer, and Chia-ch'ing's (1760-1820) first empress, the daughter


185

of an Imperial Household Department manager (Torbert 1977:76). Two of Ch'ien-lung's concubines probably also came from bondservant families; the father of another was a Korean bondservant (ibid.). Two of Chia-ch'ing's concubines were initially palace maids (ibid., 75). One of K'ang-hsi's favorites was in fact of still lower status: her father was a state slave (sin jeku jetere aha ) (ibid., 75; Yeh 1984:45). Information in the imperial genealogy on the fathers of two other imperial concubines—K'ang-hsi's Cheng fei and Chia-ch'ing's Shun-pin—suggests that they too may have come from bondservant backgrounds.

The hsiu-nü and palace maid drafts enabled the emperors to exercise the right of first choice over the daughters of officials in the regular Manchu, Mongol, and Han banners as well as in the upper three bondservant banners linked to the Imperial Household Department. The social status of the emperor's affines was mixed; it included aristocrats and slaves (the bond-servants). The inclusion of the latter, in direct contravention of rules forbidding intermarriage between bannermen and bondservants (HPTL 1.29a:-30a), is a most striking aspect of the Ch'ing marriage system.

Unlike the native Chinese dynasties studied by Holmgren, the Ch'ing tried to regulate the access of both affinal/maternal and sororal kin. By the early eighteenth century girls closely related to the empress or descended through their mothers from the Aisin Gioro line had to be explicitly identified as such in the hsiu-nü inspections. From 1800 the throne began issuing exemptions from the hsiu-nü draft to daughters of imperial princesses married to Mongols, sisters of the empress, empress dowager, and concubines of the first through fourth ranks. These regulations did not bar girls born to brothers of the empress and concubines of the first four ranks from the draft, and, as we have seen, imperial consorts were frequently related to one another. In the final analysis, it was not the policy governing selection of wives but the rejection of eldest-son (or empress's son) succession and the inclusion of low-status bondservant daughters in the harem that served as a check on the emergence of powerful affinal or sororal relatives.

The Status of Wives and Concubines

Ebrey (1986) and Rubie Watson (see her chapter in this volume) have argued that commoners in Sung and contemporary China have not had polygynous unions because stringent ritual, legal, and social distinctions separated the wife ("first wife" in this chapter) from all other sexual partners. Holmgren (in this volume) has called the Chinese system "serial monogamy." According to Watson, concubines were sharply differentiated from wives in three critical aspects: their mode of entry into the household, their ritual obligations and privileges, and their social status. Wives entered their husbands'


186

households with dowries; concubines did not. Concubines were purchased. The marriage rite was performed only for the wife; there could be serial marriages, but a man could have only one wife at a time. All children called the first wife "mother," and their filial obligations were directed to her and not to their natural mothers. Concubines were usually not commemorated after death, unlike wives. Wives came from respectable families with standing in their community, and marriage created a sustained relationship between the wife-givers and wife-takers, as contrasted to the complete absence of such relationships with a concubine's natal family, which was by definition of low status.

The Ch'ing imperial marriage system was not fully polygamous. As 'we have noted earlier, the concubines in the imperial harem were graded into a seven-rank hierarchy differentiated with respect to privilege and living allowances. Nowhere in the Ch'ing annals do we have true polygamy as described by Holmgren in her characterization of non-Han regimes in this volume, where all wives, or a group of senior wives, enjoyed equal status.

In other important respects, however, the Ch'ing system did not conform to the Chinese imperial system, described by Holmgren. Unlike the sons of Han Chinese rulers, the sons of the empress and of concubines were not clearly distinguished. And we shall see that the Ch'ing system also differed significantly from the system of monogamy practiced in Western Europe in permitting concubines' sons to be legitimate heirs to the throne. Furthermore, in contrast to the marriage system of native Chinese states (see Holmgren's essay in this volume), the Ch'ing allowed concubines to be promoted to empress.

Unlike the marriage system of Chinese commoners cited by Watson, the imperial system failed to sharply distinguish between the mode of entry, social status, and ritual obligations and privileges of the wife and concubines. Many empresses (seven of the eighteen women who held the status of empress during the dynasty, either during their lives or posthumously) entered the imperial harem as concubines, yet they (as empresses) received the same ritual investiture, emoluments, and privileges granted to the women who had entered as wives. This was also true for the six other concubines who were promoted to empress dowager only after the death of their spouse.

We have earlier noted that the Ch'ing rejection of the principle of eldest-son succession and the refusal to announce the heir until the emperor lay dying produced bitter succession struggles. The Ch'ing did not honor the principle, found in both the Ming and the Mongol dynasties, of favoring the sons of the first wife as heir. Did the status of the mother affect the choice of the heir? Historians cite the case of Yin-ssu, the K'ang-hsi emperor's eighth son by a woman of slave background (Liang fei). When Yin-jeng, K'ang-hsi's son by his empress, proved to be unfit for the throne, factions began to form around other potential contenders for the succession. Silas Wu


187

notes that Yin-ssu's mother's low birth counted against him (1979:163), but apparently not sufficiently to disqualify him from consideration.

The Yung-cheng emperor was himself the son of a Manchu "maidservant in the palace" (Hummel 1944 2:916). Despite producing six children for the emperor, Yung-cheng's mother was ranked by K'ang-hsi only as a fei ; her promotion to empress dowager came at her son's hands. Ch'ien-lung's mother, a Niohuru, was nonetheless the daughter of a middle-level servant (assistant majordomo) in Yung-cheng's princely household; she entered his establishment in 1704, gave birth to the future emperor in 1711, but was not promoted to the third rank (fei ) until 1723-24, about the time her son was secretly designated heir-apparent (Kahn 1971:88). A kuei-fei when Yung-cheng died, she was named empress dowager by her son. The mother of the Chia-ch'ing emperor was from a bondservant family who entered the Ch'ien-lung emperor's harem as a concubine of the fourth rank. In the course of producing six children, she was gradually promoted to concubine of the first rank before her death in 1775 and was posthumously elevated to empress in 1795 when her son was designated heir-apparent. In fact, of the ten emperors who reigned in the Ch'ing dynasty, only one (Tao-kuang) was the son of a first wife or empress. In short, contrary to the Yin-ssu example, the imperial succession did not exclude sons of concubines; it did not prohibit the succession of sons from low-status mothers.

Mode of Entry and Social Status

No imperial concubines were purchased. In contrast to the customary Han Chinese practice, many imperial concubines entered the harem through the same hsiu-nü draft that selected empresses (see table 5.3 for ranks of entering consorts). As noted earlier, empresses and concubines of the first five ranks (C1-C6 in the table) were most likely selected through the hsiu-nü draft, while the lower-ranking concubines tended to have entered the palace as maidservants through the kung-nü recruitment process discussed earlier. Of the 155 women in the harems of the ten Ch'ing emperors, 76 percent entered as concubines through the hsiu-nü draft; i.e., they were chosen in the same way as were empresses (see table 5.3).

Many concubines came from the Manchu aristocratic lines that also provided empresses. When Shun-chih's second empress was installed in 1654, her younger sister also entered his harem as a concubine of the third rank. The younger sister of K'ang-hsi's empress entered K'ang-hsi's harem some decades later, gave him a son (1691), and was posthumously made a consort of the third rank after she died in 1696. K'ang-hsi's second empress was a daughter of Ebilun, a major personage of his day and son of Eidu, founder of the Niohuru clan; yet she entered the harem as a concubine of the third rank and was not made empress until 1677, less than a year before her death. The daughter of T'ung Kuo-wei, a major military leader, entered K'ang-hsi's


188

TABLE 5.3
Mode of Entry of Empress and Concubines

 

Entered as

Emperor

C1

C2

C3

C4

C5

C6

C7

C8

C9

Shun-chih

2

0

0

3

1

0

10

3

0

K'ang-hsi

1

0

4

3

2

7

19

4

0

Yung-cheng

1

2

0

1

0

2

0

0

3

Ch'ien-lung

1

2

0

0

1

17

0

7

1

Chia-ch'ing

1

1

2

0

0

6

0

4

0

Tao-kuang

2

1

0

0

1

9

0

7

0

Hsien-feng

1

0

0

0

2

10

2

1

0

T'ung-chih

1

0

0

1

2

1

0

0

0

Kuang-hsu

1

0

0

2

0

0

0

0

0

Hsuan-t'ung

Totals

11

6

6

10

9

52

31

26

4

SOURCES : TCYT , supplemented with information from AHCL , T'ang 1993, and Yü 1985b:57 on the Hsien-feng Emperor.

NOTE : C1 = empress; C2 = huang-kuei-fei ; C3 = kuei-fei ; C4 = fei ; C5 = pin ; C6 = kuei-jen ; C7 = shu-fei, ch'ang-tsai , or ta-ying ; C8 = palace service; C9 = other.

harem as a concubine of the second rank and was made empress in 1689, only one day before her death. The Kuang-hsu emperor's Tatara concubines were the granddaughters of a prominent provincial official, Yü-t'ai (TCYT ; Hummel 1943 1:158-59).

Our discussion of the social backgrounds of concubines' families can be expanded. Table 5.4, which presents the clan affiliations of all imperial and princely consorts, includes 465 women, more than five times the number of imperial and princely first wives (cf. table 5.2). Again, the clustering of affines indicates that emperors and princes took their wives from a common pool (cf. table 5.2). This must of course be the case when the heir-apparent is not announced at an early age. Many of the bondservant women were concubines of low rank: among imperial concubines, for example, four of the seven Ch'en women never rose above the fifth rank, and only one, who had begun as a household servant, rose to the first rank. Miss Chang, who 'remained a lowly shu-fei despite giving birth to two daughters, and one each of the Lius and Wangs also entered as palace maids. Most had low rank; only two attained the title of concubine of the first rank.

What is equally striking, however, is the dominance of Manchu aristocratic clans like the Nara, the Niohuru, the Fuca, and the Guwalgiya in this larger group of concubines. A finding that indirectly supports our argument that imperial concubines were not sharply differentiated from first wives lies in the varied ranks achieved by the women given by the Niohuru to the


189

TABLE 5.4
Leading Affines of Emperors and Princes

Affines

Imperial

Princely

Total

Number of consortsa

173

294

467

From families with one marriage

41

61

102

From families with two marriages

20

24

44

Mongol affines

25

25

50

Leading affines Chang

1

8

9

Ch'en

7

7

14

Fuca

5

12

17

Guwalgiya

2b

18b

20

Heseri

6

1

7

Irgen Gioro

5

10

15

Li

3

17

20

Liu

4

13

17

Nara

7

18

25

Niohuru

15

8

23

Wang

3

13

16

Yehe Nara

9

4

l3

Other surnames

20

55

75

SOURCE:TCYT , T'ang 1923.

a Excludes twelve imperial and two princely consorts whose surnames are unknown.

b Includes Suwan Guwalgiya.

imperial house: they ranged from empress (seven) down to shu-fei (two). The Fuca daughters in the imperial harems included one empress and four concubines, none of whom was below the fourth rank. In contrast, the ranks achieved by the Nara women did not rise above the third-ranking fei and included some with the rank of shu-fei .

Entry into the imperial harem marked the onset of sustained relations between the concubine's family and the emperor, just as in the case of families providing a wife. It was the immediate gains, not the long-term rewards, of being related to a future emperor that induced respectable, even powerful families to give their daughters as concubines or ladies-in-waiting to princes and emperors. If the girl won the emperor's favor, her father's and brothers' careers would be transformed. Osi, father of the Shun-chih emperor's favorite concubine, was promoted from viscount to third-class earl "as a favor to his daughter" (Hummel 1943 1:301). Fiyanggu, the father of Yung-cheng's empress, was posthumously made a first-rank duke (PCTC 151.106). Chin Chien, the brother of Shu chia huang-kuei-fei, rose to become president of the Board of Works and the Board of Civil Appointments after his sister became Ch'ien-lung's favorite. Imperial favor raised A-pu-nai, the father of


190

K'ang-hsi's Liang fei, from slave to bondservant; it freed Kao Pin, the father of Ch'ien-lung's Hui-hsien huang-kuei-fei, from bondservitude, and Kao eventually became a grand secretary (Torbert 1977:75-76).

Imperial favor could transfer bannermen to the prestigious upper three banners—the Bordered Yellow, Plain Yellow, and Plain White—which had come under the emperor's control in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. In addition to T'ung Kuo-kang and T'ung Kuo-wei—who with their descendants were moved from the Chinese Plain Blue Banner to the Manchu Bordered Yellow Banner in 1688 (their sister was the K'ang-hsi emperor's mother)—we have the example of Ch'ung Ch'i, father of T'ung-chih's empress, who was shifted with his descendants from the Mongol Plain Blue Banner to the Manchu Bordered Yellow Banner after his daughter's marriage. Ch'ung Ch'i was also promoted to third-class duke as a sign of favor (Hummel 1943 1:208-9). Tz'u-hsi's branch of the Yehe Nara was also shifted from the Bordered Blue to the Bordered Yellow Banner after she became empress dowager in 1862 (Yü 1985b:127). Best of all, the imperial favor could wipe out career failure. Tz'u-hsi's father, Hui-cheng, died in official disgrace during the Taiping rebellion (1853); when Tz'u-hsi became empress dowager, she posthumously made him a third-grade duke (ibid., 133).

Ritual Incorporation

Whereas concubines in Han Chinese commoner households were purchased and entered without dowries or the wedding ritual, upper-ranking imperial concubines entered with dowries through the same process that selected empresses. Following precedents set by earlier dynasties (Soullière 1987: 179-85), the rituals of investiture for concubines of the upper four ranks were graded variations of the rituals that accompanied the taking of an empress. Although we shall focus on these rites of incorporation, we should note that postmortem commemoration in the Temple of the Ancestors and empirewide observance of their death days (Rawski 1988:236, 247) were accorded to all empresses and empress dowagers, regardless of their original status.

The model for all ranks was the "great wedding" (ta-hun ), carried out when a reigning monarch took an empress, which followed the Chinese imperial tradition concerning wedding rituals. During the entire dynasty, this ritual was carried out only five times. Marriage, the event that marked the coming of age, was a necessary prelude to the end of a regency for a child emperor. The Shun-chih emperor, six sui when he was put on the throne in 1643, was married with the full rites in 1651 at the age of fourteen sui ; K'ang-hsi, who ascended the throne at eight sui , was married at the age of twelve sui in 1665; T'ung-chih, who became emperor at six sui , was married at seventeen sui ; and Kuang-hsu, who was four sui when he ascended the throne, was married at age nineteen (TCYT ; also Hsin 1985).


191

The celebration of the imperial nuptials was an empirewide event that involved every citizen. During a "great wedding" (in 1888 lasting a total of twenty days) no punishments could be meted out. Officials wore special robes to mark the auspicious event; on the actual wedding day, everyone in the empire was required to wear red and green, the streets through which the wedding procession passed were cleaned, and the palace was decorated and refurbished. Of course, the state altars of Heaven and Earth as well as the ancestors were notified (with sacrifices) of the event, which was thus part of state as well as family ritual.

The sequence of events that comprised an imperial wedding began when the empress dowager, in consultation with the imperial princes, chose a bride (Wang Shu-ch'ing 1980; TCHTSL c. 324) and "ordered" the emperor to marry. To fix the betrothal (na-ts'ai li ), two emissaries went with gifts (prescribed in the regulations)[20] and the imperial edict announced the betrothal to the mansion of the bride's father. Here the chief emissary read the edict aloud before the bride's father, who performed the full ritual obeisance (three prostrations, nine kowtows) in acknowledgment of the imperial grace. This betrothal ceremony was followed by a second, the ta-cheng li, when items to be used in the wedding itself were delivered to the bride's house by the emissaries, who announced the wedding date selected by the Board of Astronomy.

The dowry, normally given by the bride's family, was in this case prepared by the Imperial Household Department. Large quantities of court clothing, jewelry, gold and silver utensils, and furniture were presented to the bride several days before the wedding day, then ceremonially carried back to the palace.[21] The core of the wedding ceremony was the conferral of the title of empress on the bride (ts'e-li ). The "gold seal" and "gold tablets" conferring the title of empress were presented to the bride at her father's house; the bride, dressed in the robes and accessories of an empress, was then carried to the palace in a sedan chair with the empress's regalia: she was the only female who (unescorted by the emperor) was permitted to enter through the Wu-men, the main gate to the palace (Shan 1960:100). The traditional nuptial chambers, in the east wing of the K'un-ning palace, were decorated with "double happiness" and other auspicious symbols (Yen Min 1980:13). The wedding ceremony was completed in the nuptial chambers, where the bride and groom sipped from the nuptial wine cup. On the next day the emperor and his bride paid their respects to the gods, immediate ancestors, and to his mother (the empress dowager). Several days later the couple received the congratulations of the court and officials; the empress dowager received congratulations; and the emperor and the empress dowager hosted banquets for the parents and relatives of the bride and bridegroom and for officials.

The "great wedding" parallels the ritual sequence found among Han


192

Chinese families. The betrothal, formalized with the presentation of gifts from the groom's family, is followed by the public transfer of the bride from her natal home to the palace, her appearance before her mother-in-law, and by banquets held to celebrate the event. But at critical points the ceremony modifies commoner practice to indicate the preeminent status of the groom. The bride's family members are his subjects; the bride's father must acknowledge the unequal relationship between wife-giver and emperor through obeisances; the rituals do not include the visit home by the bride, which was customary after a commoner wedding.

Gift exchanges also reflect the inequality of status between bride and groom. Here, as in the marriages of princes and princesses, the betrothal ceremony and the ta-cheng li are marked by presentations of gold, silver, livestock, furs, textiles, court clothing, and court accessories (including jewels) from the emperor to the bride, her mother, her father, her grandfather, and even her brothers. The banquet, held at the bride's father's house after the na-ts'ai rite, is provided by the Imperial Household Department and not by the bride's father. The Imperial Household Department provides all of the "dowry" as well as the bridewealth (Li P'eng-nien 1983) in a deliberate inversion of the commoner custom, which had the bride's family providing a dowry.

Archival documents concerning the "great weddings" of the T'ung-chih and Kuang-hsu emperors and information on the wedding of P'u-i, which was closely modeled on these historical precedents, provide evidence that imperial concubines entered the harem with rituals that resembled the taking of an empress. In the two "great weddings" of the nineteenth century, the empress's entry into the palace was preceded by the entry of concubines from highly ranked families. Four concubines, one of whom was the paternal aunt of the empress, entered the palace during the T'ung-chih emperor's "great wedding"; two sisters became the Kuang-hsu emperor's concubines during his "great wedding." And we know that the runner-up among the girls considered for empress was selected as his concubine during P'u-i's "great wedding" (P'u 1982).

A concubine also entered the palace with a "dowry" provided by the Imperial Household Department (KCTC nos. 2381, 2385; PAPS no. 2102). Unlike commoner women, whose namelessness reflected their subordinate status in Chinese society (R. Watson 1986), concubines of the upper four ranks, like empresses, were granted individual titles in life, and occasionally in death. The ritual for installation of concubines in the first three ranks, like the ceremonies for the installation of the empress, was also held in the T'ai-ho tien, the hall that was the center for court and state ritual (KCTL c. 2; TCHTSL c. 306). The patents of rank (a seal and tablets inscribed with the concubine's rank and name similar to those made for empresses and empresses dowager) were created whenever a woman was named to the first three


193

ranks of concubines; concubines of the fourth rank were installed with a gold tablet but no seal. The investiture of concubines of the first three ranks was marked by sacrifices at the Temple of the Ancestors and the Feng-hsien-tien on the day preceding the ceremony to notify the ancestors about the event; this was omitted for the investiture of a fourth-ranking concubine.

Concubines selected for a "great wedding" received these symbols of rank in their father's house before they were conveyed to the palace (P'u 1982: 129). In 1872 the two fourth-ranking and one fifth-ranking concubines entered the palace two days before the empress. The third-ranking concubine joined them the next day. After entering the palace, all concubines worshiped before the ancestral portraits, paid their respects to the empresses dowager, and lit incense before the Buddhist altar in the palace in which they were to reside in a ritual that the new empress would herself perform the day after the nuptials (KCTC nos. 2379, 2381, 2383; P'u 1982:129).

The archival materials indicate that the ritual distinctions between the wife and concubines found in commoner households were not present in the Ch'ing system of imperial marriage. The rituals accompanying installation of imperial concubines of the first through fourth ranks resembled those for the installation of an empress: patents of ranks were conferred with prior notification of the ancestors, and the newcomer performed domestic rituals before the palace equivalent of the domestic altar. The only ritual distinction enjoyed solely by the empress in a "great wedding" was her entry through the main gate;[22] concubines entered the palace through the Shen-wu, or back door. In a "great wedding," the newly installed concubines served as ladies-in-waiting for the empress on her wedding day and participated in the rites that took place on that occasion. They were also included in the major domestic court rituals that involved the empress during the course of the year (KTCL c. 2).

Not all concubines were so thoroughly integrated into the imperial family, however. The rituals show a clear distinction between the four highest ranks and lower-ranking concubines, who received no patents and who entered the palace without prior sacrifice at the ancestral altars (TCHTSL :306). These lower-ranking concubines were also the women most vulnerable to omission from the imperial genealogy.[23] At the same time, as we have already observed, it was entirely possible for even these low-ranking concubines to be promoted and even to attain the rank of empress.

Conclusion

The marriage patterns of the Ch'ing imperial house had a direct effect on the structure of power within Ch'ing society. Marriage exchange with banner allies was a vital element in the supraethnic policies of the early Manchu rulers during the conquest period. Later emperors confronted a different


194

issue: how to prevent. the Manchus from being completely assimilated into the Han Chinese population that they ruled. Although banner troops were stationed in separate garrisoned quarters in major cities in China, there were clear signs in the mid-eighteenth century of the loss of Manchu language skills among bannermen and indications that Manchu dress and other customs were being supplanted by Chinese norms. It is no accident that this was precisely the period that Manchu tradition and social structure were "fixed" by being written down; the concern with preservation of Manchu ethnicity voiced by the Ch'ien-lung emperor and his successors undoubtedly helped to perpetuate the prohibition against intermarriage with Han Chinese.

As Jennifer Holmgren points out in her chapter in this volume, the relation between marriage and politics is highly complex and variable. The Ch'ing system of political endogamy reinforced the historical master-servant tie of the Aisin Gioro with bannermen. The Ch'ing prohibition on marriage with Han Chinese outside the banner system removed Chinese officials from using this avenue to heighten their power: in contrast to the Chinese traditional historiography, which placed Chinese at the heart of the Ch'ing political system, our study suggests that they were only peripheral players in marriage politics.

The Ch'ing pattern of intermarriage with bannermen can be contrasted with the Northern Sung imperial house studied by Chaffee in this volume. Northern Sung emperors forged marriage alliances with the civil elite—or, more precisely, the civil elite residing in or near the Northern Sung capital—as a means of winning over potential rivals. The Ch'ing, like the Ming rulers (Soullière 1988), deliberately avoided marriages with the civil elite in an effort to prevent imperial consorts and their relatives from obtaining access to political power. At the same time, as we noted earlier, the Northern Sung, Ming, and Ch'ing rulers all used marriage as a means of reinforcing their bonds with the military elite.

The Ch'ing succession system also altered the structure of power within the harem. By rejecting the Ming principle of eldest-son succession, the Ch'ing made the sons of all consorts eligible to become emperor. As we have seen, the Ch'ing (like the Ming) took consorts from both the very top and the very bottom of the banner hierarchy: daughters of noble households mingled and competed for the emperor's favor with maids from bondservant families. Recruitment policies allowed distant sororal and maternal relations to enter the harem, where each served as a check on the others. The deliberate social fluidity among consorts and the possibility of having an "upstart" triumph over her social betters served as an institutionalized check on the political ambitions of any particular group among the banner elite.

The Ch'ing tried to make usurpation more difficult by widening the circle of potential competitors for imperial favor. We have been at some pains to demonstrate that on critical questions like succession, the sons of lower-


195

ranking concubines could and frequently did win out over rivals with mothers of higher rank. The fluidity of succession subverted the hierarchical order of the harem and served to check the emergence of powerful imperial affines. When we survey the history of the dynasty, the problem of powerful affines is conspicuously absent.

In this chapter we have argued that the criteria used to determine the absence of polygyny among Chinese commoner families reveal that Ch'ing imperial marriage practices differ so markedly as to constitute a separate marriage model—one that is neither monogamy nor polygyny. Why then did the Ch'ing so emphasize hierarchy and gradations of rank in the ritual installation and living allowances of concubines?

Maurice Bloch has noted that rituals are not necessarily faithful reflections of social reality; rather, "the roles that people act in rituals do not reflect or define social status. . . . These roles are part of a drama that creates an image . . . that needs to be created because in many ways it contradicts what everybody knows" (1986:45). Chinese commoner families emphasize the primacy of the first wife precisely because in many cases it is not the first wife but a younger concubine who wins the master's affections and threatens to disrupt family harmony by her power to obtain an unfair share of the family's resources. The institutionalized emphasis on the primacy of the first wife aims to keep family tensions under control so that the patriline can be perpetuated. The vulnerability of the Ch'ing empress, who was frequently chosen without regard for the emperor's personal wishes, is compounded by her rivals' powerful relatives and elite social backgrounds. Nor, as the case of Tz'u-hsi demonstrates, did the empress installed during her husband's lifetime have more power because of her ritual superiority than the mother promoted to empress dowager by her son. The ritual acknowledgment of the empress as the head of the harem preserved the illusion of order in a situation that was in reality extremely fluid and dependent on the whims of the ruler.

If empresses were frequently only nominal heads of imperial harems, there could be no doubt that in the Ch'ing, as in virtually every dynasty, the emperor's mother, the empress dowager, did exercise real authority and power. Her legitimacy was firmly grounded in Confucian teachings: the highly publicized exercises in filial piety of the K'ang-hsi and Ch'ien-lung emperors may have been politically manipulative (S. Wu 1979; Kahn 1971), but the affection these rulers bore their grandmothers and mothers was no less real for all that.

Empresses dowager were frequently joined in the inner court councils by imperial princes, the agnates of the collateral branches of the ruling house. The Ch'ing succession system permitted younger sons to participate in government and to vie for the ultimate prize, the throne. The Ch'ing thus differs from native Chinese regimes, which barred nonheirs from politics and power. Throughout the dynasty, we find both imperial agnates and emperors' sons


196

being appointed to carry out substantive tasks. These assignments continued even after the emperors had successfully overcome the collegial traditions of rule that had characterized most of the seventeenth century. The K'ang-hsi emperor tested his eldest son by making him regent while he himself led troops against the Western Mongols; he sent another son to command the Ch'ing banners in another campaign (S. Wu 1979). Imperial princes took civil service positions in the ministries; they also served as administrators in the banners and the Imperial Clan Court.

In the late seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, the political activities of imperial agnates were never a threat to the throne because of the strong leadership provided by the emperors. During the late nineteenth century, however, with a succession of infant-emperors, imperial agnates played leading roles in national politics. Prince Kung, son of the Tao-kuang emperor, was designated to handle negotiations with the foreign powers in 1860 when his half brother the Hsien-feng emperor fled Peking; of the four adjutants-general who were in charge in the capital in the last months of the Hsien-feng reign, three were imperial agnates and one was an imperial affine (Hummel 1944 2:666, 668, 924).

In the period from 1862 to 1897 China's government was dominated by the empress dowager Tz'u-hsi, who ruled not so much with the help of her natal kin as with the support of her husband's half brothers. The struggle for power that followed the Hsien-feng emperor's death was between two factions dominated by imperial agnates: the empress dowagers Tz'u-an and Tz'u-hsi (the biological mother of the T'ung-chih emperor) won this contest with the help of their brother-in-law, Prince Kung (Wright 1966:16-17). This alliance of imperial princes and the empresses dowager continued in the subsequent Kuang-hsu reign (Kwong 1984; Hummel 1943:384-86), when Prince Ch'un, father of the emperor and Tz'u-hsi's brother-in-law, enjoyed great influence at court. The marriage and succession practices of the Ch'ing had succeeded in preventing substantive political challenges to the throne from affines, but could not guard against challenges from agnates. The Manchu traditions of collegial rule by imperial agnates reemerged during the last decades of Ch'ing governance.


199

Glossary

ch'ang-tsaiinline image

chi-fuinline image

chin-paoinline image

chin-shihinline image

chin-ts'einline image

ch'u-tinginline image

chuang-lieninline image

chuang-yuaninline image

efuinline image

feiinline image

feng-yinginline image

ho-ch'ininline image

hsiu-nüinline image

huang-kuei-feiinline image

ko-koinline image

kuei-feiinline image

kuei-jeninline image

Ku-lun kung-chu inline image

kung-nüinline image

Li fan yuaninline image

na-ts'ai liinline image

pininline image

Shang-shu-fang inline image

shih-nüinline image

shu-feiinline image

shu fujininline image

suiinline image

ta-cheng liinline image

ta-huninline image

ta-yinginline image

ti fujininline image

ts'e-fenginline image

ts'e fujininline image

ts'e-liinline image

tsung-jen fuinline image

tsung-shihinline image

weninline image

wuinline image

ying-ch'iehinline image

References

Primary Sources

AHCL Ai-hsin chueh-lo tsung-p'uinline image. 1937-38 edition.

Ch'in-ting ta-Ch'ing t'ung-liinline image.

CTKTSH Ch'ing-tai kung-t'ing sheng-huoinline image . 1985; reprint, Taipei: Nan-t'ien shu-chü, 1986.

HPTL Ch'in-ting hu-pu tse-liinline image. 1865 edition.

KCTL Ch'in-ting kung-chung hsien-hsing tse-liinline image. 1865 edition.

KCTC Palace affairs (kung-chung tsa-chien), Rituals (li-i) section, Number One Historical Archives, Peking.

LYYS Taken from the Grand Secretariat (Nei-ko) memorials deposited in the Institute of History and Philology, Academia Sinica, Taipei. Only one document, dated Shun-chih 10, tenth month, sixth day-1 (A17-166), was used in this paper.

NWFTL Tsung-kuan Nei-wu-fu hsien-hsing tse-liinline image. 1937 edition.

PAPS Palace affairs, personnel section, Number One Historical Archives, Peking.

PCTC Ch'in-ting pa-ch'i t'ung-chihinline image. 1739 edition.

T'ang Pang-chih inline image. 1923. Ch'ing huang-shih ssu-p'uinline image. Reprint, Taipei: Wen-hai, 1966.

TCHTSL Ch'in-ting ta-Ch'ing hui-tien shih-liinline image. 1899 edition.


200

TCSL Ta Ch'ing Shih-tsu Chang-huang-ti shih-luinline image. 1937-38; reprint, Taipei: Taiwan Hua-wen shu-chü, 1964.

TCYT Ta Ch'ing yü-tiehinline image. Number One Historical Archives, Peking. MS. Utah Genealogical Society, Salt Lake City, Utah, microfilm.

TJFTL Ch'in-ting tsung-jen-fu tse-liinline image. 1908 edition.

Secondary Sources

An Shuang-ch'eng inline image. 1983. "Shun, K'ang, Yung san-ch'ao pa-ch'i ting-e ch'ien-hsi" inline image (Analysis of Eight Banner strengths in the first three Ch'ing reigns). Li-shih tang-an, no. 2:100-103.

Bawden, C. R. 1968. The Modern History of Mongolia. New York: Praeger.

Bloch, Maurice. 1986. From Blessing to Violence: History and Ideology in the Circumcision Ritual of the Merina of Madagascar. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Brunnert, H. S., and V. V. Hagelstrom. 1911. Present Day Political Organization of China. Rev. N. T. Kolessoff, trans. A. Beltchenko and E. E. Moran. Peking.

Chao, Yun-t'ien inline image. 1984. "Ch'ing-tai ti 'pei-chih c-fu' chih-tu" inline image (The institution for picking imperial sons-in-law in the Ch'ing). Ku-kung po-wu-yuan yuan-k'an, no. 4:28-37.

Ch'en, Chia-hua inline image. 1984. "Pa-ch'i chih-tu yen-chiu shu-lueh" inline image (Survey of research on the Eight Banner system). She-hui k'o-hsueh chi-k'an, nos. 5:109-16, 6:113-20.

Chou Yuan-lien inline image and Chao Shih-yü inline image. 1986. Huang fu she cheng wang To-erh-kun ch'üan chuaninline image (The complete biography of Imperial Father Regent Dorgon). Ch'angch'un: Kirin Memoirs Press.

Chung, Priscilla Ching. 1981. Palace Women in the Northern Sung, 960-1126. Leiden: E.J. Brill.

Crossley, Pamela. 1983. "The Tong in Two Worlds: Cultural Identities in Liaodong and Nurgan during the 13th-17th Centuries." Ch'ing-shih wen-t'i 4.9:21-46.

———. 1987. "Manzhou yuanliu kao and the Formalization of the Manchu Heritage." Journal of Asian Studies 46.4:761-90.

———. 1989. "The Qianlong Retrospect on the Chinese-Martial (Hanjun) Banners." Late Imperial China 10.1:63-107.

Ebrey, Patricia. 1986. "Concubines in Sung China." Journal of Family History 11.1:1-24.

Feng, Han-yi. 1967. The Chinese Kinship System. Harvard-Yenching Institute Studies 22. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Fletcher, Joseph. 1978. "Ch'ing Inner Asia c. 1800." In The Cambridge History of China, vol. 10, ed. John K. Fairbank. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 35-106.

———. 1979. "Turco-Mongolian Monarchic Tradition in the Ottoman Empire." In Eucharisterion, ed. Ihor Sevcenko and Frank E. Sysyn, pt. 1, pp. 236-51. Cambridge, Mass.: Ukrainian Research Institute.

Gallin, Bernard. 1963. "Cousin Marriage in China." Ethnology 2.1:104-08.

Harrell, Stevan, Susan Naquin, and Deyuan Ju. 1985. "Lineage Genealogy: The Genealogical Records of the Qing Imperial Lineage." Late Imperial China 6.2:37-47.

Holmgren, Jennifer. 1986. "Observations on Marriage and Inheritance Practices in


201

Early Mongol and Yuan Society, with Particular Reference to the Levirate." Journal of Asian History 20:127-92.

Hou Shou-ch'ang inline image. 1982. "K'ang-hsi mu-hsi k'ao" inline image (On the maternal ancestors of the K'ang-hsi emperor). Li-shih tang-an, no. 4:100-105.

Hsin Hao inline image. 1985. "Kuang-hsu ta-hun tien-li tang-an" inline image (Records relating to the Kuang-hsu emperor's wedding rite). Li-shih tang-an, no. 2:132-34.

Hsu, Francis L. K. 1967. Under the Ancestors' Shadow: Kinship, Personality and Social Mobility in China. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Reissue, 1971.

Hua Li inline image. 1983. "Ch'ing-tai ti Man-Meng lien-yin" inline image (Marriage alliances of Manchus and Mongols in the Ch'ing). Min-tsu yen-chiu, no. 2:45-54, 79.

Huang, Pei. 1974. Autocracy, at Work: A Study of the Yung-cheng Period, 1723-1735. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.

———. inline image. 1986. "Ch'ing-ch'u ti Man-chou kuei-tsu (1583-1795)—Niu-hu-lu tsu" inline image (1583-1795)— inline image (The early Manchu aristocracy: the Niohuru clan, 1583-1795). In Lao Chen-i hsien-sheng pa-chih jung-ch'ing lun-wen chiinline image (Festschrift for Professor Lao Chen-i), comp. Lao Chen-i hsien-sheng pa-chih jung-ch'ing lun-wen chi pien-chi wei-yuan-hui inline image, pp. 629-64. Taipei: Commercial Press.

Hummel, Arthur W., ed. 1943-44. Eminent Chinese of the Ch'ing Period. 2 vols. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.

Kahn, Harold L. 1971. Monarchy in the Emperor's Eyes: Image and Reality in the Ch'ien-lung Reign. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Kessler, Lawrence D. 1976. K'ang-hsi and the Consolidation of Ch'ing Rule, 1661-1684. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Krader, Lawrence. 1963. Social Organization of the Mongol-Turkic Pastoral Nomads. The Hague: Mouton.

Kwong, Luke S. K. 1984. A Mosaic of the Hundred Days: Personalities, Politics, and Ideas of 1898. Cambridge: Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University.

Lattimore, Owen. 1934. The Mongols of Manchuria: Their Tribal Divisions, Geographical Distribution, Historical Relations with Manchus and Chinese and Present Political Problems. New York: John Day.

Li Feng-min inline image. 1984. "Ho-shih kung-chu Mu-k'u-shih ti hun-p'ei wen-t'i" inline image (The marriage problem of Princess Mukushih). Ku-kung po-wu-yuan yuan-k'an, no. 2:26.

Li Hsueh-chih inline image. 1985. "Man-chou min-tsu ch'u-hsing ch'i chih hun-yin hsi-su" inline image (Marriage customs of the Manchus in the early period). Pien-cheng yen-chiu-so nien-pao (Kuo-li cheng-chih ta-hsueh) 16:45-65.

Li P'eng-nien inline image. 1983. "Kuang-hsu-ti ta-hun pei-pan hao-yung kai-shu" inline image (A general study of the expenditures for the Kuang-hsu emperor's wedding). Ku-kung po-wu-yuan yuan-k'an, no. 2:80-86.

Lu Kung inline image. 1982. "Huang-t'ai-hou ho kung-nü ti sheng-huo tai-yü" inline image (The life conditions of the empress dowager and the palace maidens). In Yen-ching ch'un-ch'iuinline image (History of the capital), comp. Pei-ching shih yen-chiu hui inline image. Peking: Pei-ching ch'u-pan-she.

Lü Ming-hui inline image. 1985. "Shih-lun Ch'ing-ch'u Man-tsu t'ung-chih che tui Meng,


202

Han ti cheng-ts'e" inline image (Early Ch'ing policy toward the Mongols and Han Chinese). Min-tsu yen-chiu, no. 3:17-22.

Macfarlane, Alan. 1986. Marriage and Love in England: Modes of Reproduction, 1300-1840. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

P'u Chia inline image. 1982. "P'u-i ta-hun chi-shih" inline image (P'u-i's wedding). In Wan Ch'ing kung-t'ing sheng-huo chien-weninline image (Life in the palace in late Ch'ing), comp. Chung-kuo jen-min cheng-chih hsieh-shang hui-yi ch'üan-kuo wei-yuan-hui inline image. Peking: Wen-shih tzu-liao ch'u-pan-she.

Rawski, Evelyn S. 1988. "The Imperial Way of Death." In Death Ritual in Late Imperial and Modern China, ed. James L. Watson and Evelyn S. Rawski, pp. 228-53. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Shan Shih-yuan inline image. 1960. "Kuan-yü Ch'ing kung ti hsiu-nü ho kung-nü" inline image (On the Ch'ing palace women). Ku-kung po-wu-yuan yuan-k'an, no. 2:97-103.

Shirokogoroff, S. M. 1924; reprint, 1973. Social Organization of the Manchus. New York: AMS Press.

Soulliüre, Ellen. 1988. "The Imperial Marriages of the Ming Dynasty." Papers on Far Eastern History 37:1-30.

Spence, Jonathan. 1966. Ts'ao Yin and the K'ang-hsi Emperor, Bondservant and Master. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Sun Hsiao-en inline image. 1985. Kuang-hsu p'ing-chuaninline image (Biography of the Kuang-hsu emperor). Shenyang: Liao-ning chiao-yü ch'u-pan-she.

Sun Wen-liang inline image and Li Chih-t'ing inline image. 1982. Ch'ing T'ai-tsung ch'üan chuaninline image (Biography of Hung Taiji). Kirin: Jen-min ch'u-pan-she.

Tao, Jing-shen. 1976. The Jurchen in Twelfth-Century China. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Torbert, Preston M. 1977. The Ch'ing Imperial Household Department: A Study of Its Organization and Principal Functions, 1661-1796. Cambridge: Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University.

Wakeman, Frederic. 1985. The Great Enterprise: The Manchu Reconstruction of Imperial Order in Seventeenth-Century China. 2 vols. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Wang Lai-yin inline image. 1983. "Ho-hsiao kung-chu—Ch'ien-lung ti ti chang-shang ming-chu" inline image (Princess Ho-hsiao—the Ch'ien-lung emperor's jewel). Tzu-chin ch'eng, no. 2:25-26.

Wang Shu-ch'ing inline image. 1980. "Ch'ing-tai huang-ti ti ta-hun" inline image (The marriages of Ch'ing emperors). Tzu-chin ch'eng, no. 2:11-12.

———. 1986. "Ch'ing-tai hou-fei" inline image (Ch'ing empresses and concubines). In Ch'ing kung shih-shihinline image (Ch'ing palace affairs), ed. Wang Shu-ch'ing and Li P'eng-nien inline image. Peking: Tzu-chin ch'eng.

Wang Tao-ch'eng inline image. 1985a. "Ts'ung Hsueh P'an sung mei tai-hsuan t'an ch'i—kuan yü Ch'ing-tai ti hsiu-nü chih-tu" inline image (From Hsüeh P'an's sending his sister to await selection—on the Ch'ing hsiu-nü system). In Pei-ching shih-yuaninline image (Historical reminiscences of Peking), comp. Pei-ching shih she-hui k'o-hsueh yen-chiu so, Pei-ching shih-yuan pien-chi pu inline image, inline image. Peking: Beijing Press.


203

———. 1985b. "Yeh-ho-na-la yü Ai-hsin chueh-lo chia-tsu" inline image (The Yehonala and the Aisin Gioro descent groups). In Hsi t'ai-houinline image (The empress dowager of the western palace), ed. Yü Ping-k'un inline image et al. Peking: Tzu-chin ch'eng.

Watson, James L. 1982. "Chinese Kinship Reconsidered: Anthropological Perspectives on Historical Research." China Quarterly 92:589-622.

Watson, Rubie S. 1986. "The Named and the Nameless: Gender and Person in Chinese Society." American Ethnologist 13.4:619-31.

Wei Ch'i inline image. 1984. "Ch'ing-tai ti-i-ts'u hsuan hsiu-nü" inline image (The first hsiu-nü selection in the Ch'ing). Tzu-chin ch'eng 26:20.

Wei Ch'ing-yuan inline image, Wu Ch'i-yen inline image, and Lu Su inline image. 1982. Ch'ing-tai nü-pi chih-tuinline image (The Ch'ing bondservant system). Peking: Chung-kuo jen-min ta-hsueh.

Wright, Mary. 1966. The Last Stand of Chinese Conservatism: The T'ung-chih Restoration, 1862-1874. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Wu, Silas. 1979. Passage to Power: K'ang-hsi and His Heir Apparent, 1661-1722. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Wu Yang inline image. 1987. "Ch'ing-tai 'E-lo-ssu tso-ling' k'ao-lueh" inline image (The Russian company in the Ch'ing). Li-shih yen-chiu, no. 5:83-84.

Yang Hsueh-ch'en inline image and Chou Yuan-lien inline image. 1986. Ch'ing-tai pa-ch'i wang-kung kuei-tsu hsing-shuai shihinline image (The rise and fall of the Eight Banner aristocracy during the Ch'ing). Shenyang: Liao-ning jen-min ch'u-pan-she.

Yang Shao-hsien inline image. 1984. "Ming-tai Meng-ku tsu hun-yin ho chia-t'ing ti t'e-tien" inline image (Special characteristics of Mongol family and marriage in the Ming). Min-tsu yen-chiu, no. 4:30-38, 15.

Yeh Chih-ju inline image. 1984. "K'ang, Yung, Ch'ien shih-ch'i hsin-che-k'u jen ti ch'eng-fen chi jen-shen kuan-hsi" inline image (The status and personal relations of hsin-che-k'u in the K'ang-hsi, Yung-cheng, and Ch'ien-lung eras). Min-tsu yen-chiu, no. 1:37-45, 36.

Yen Ch'ung-nien inline image. 1983. Nu-erh-ha-ch'ih chuaninline image (Biography of Nurgaci). Peking: Jen-min ch'u-pan-she.

Yen. Min inline image. 1980. "Ti hou chieh-hun ti tung-fang" inline image (The imperial nuptial chamber). Tzu-chin ch'eng, no. 2:13.

Yü Ping-k'un inline image. 1985a. "Tz'u-hsi chia shih k'ao" inline image (Tz'u-hsi's family background). Ku-kung po-wu-yuan yuan-k'an, nos. 3:127-33, 111; 4:9-17.

———. 1985b. "Tz'u-hsi ju-kung shih-chien, shen-fen, ho feng-hao" inline image, inline image (The date of Tz'u-hsi's entry into the palace, her status and title). In Hsi-t'ai-houinline image (Empress Dowager Tz'u-hsi), by Yü Ping-k'un et al. Peking: Tzu-chin ch'eng.


204

Six
Grooming a Daughter for Marriage
Brides and Wives in the Mid-Ch'ing Period

Susan Mann

The bride's dowry at eighteen means nothing;
The grandmother's funeral at eighty tells all.
NINGPO SAYING (HO CHU 1973:227)


inline image

Marriage was the ladder of success for women in late imperial China. Even the bride who began with a modest wedding ("three cups of weak tea and a bow at the family shrine") could end her life in bounty ("mouth full of sweetcakes, playing with grandsons"). A lavish dowry nonetheless meant something: it testified to the bride's family's status (Harrell and Dickey 1985), and it was likely to complement generous betrothal gifts, one gauge of the groom's ability to provide for a daughter's long-term security (Parish and Whyte 1978:180-83). In a society that frowned upon remarriage, an extravagant dowry marked a family's confidence that their daughter would marry only once. In addition, dowry provided an awesome public display, enabling the dowered bride to enter her new home with style and dignity. Perhaps most important of all, dowry that clearly matched or exceeded the likely betrothal gifts and wedding costs shouldered by the groom's family meant that the bride was not being sold. The pervasive traffic in women is described elsewhere in this volume by Rubie Watson and Gail Hershatter. The dowered bride belonged to that select category of women who were "espoused by betrothal" (p'in tse wei ch'i ), chosen for their virtue to become wives, distinguished forever from concubines or courtesans.[1]

During the mid-Ch'ing period, dowry was the hallmark of a respectable wedding. Commoners went into debt and postponed marriages in order to dower their daughters in style. Whereas during the Sung period, as discussed in Ebrey's chapter here, the dowry was above all an upper-class

The author gratefully acknowledges research support from the Academic Senate Faculty Research Committee at the University of California, Santa Cruz. Fu Poshek and Yue Zumou provided invaluable research assistance. For critical readings of early drafts, I wish to thank Stevan Harrell, Robert Moeller, G. William Skinner, and participants in the conference, especially the editors and Diane Owen Hughes, Gail Hershatter, and Susan Naquin.


205

concern—families complained about expensive dowries because they dissipated corporate estates—in Ch'ing times dowry givers quite clearly included families of more modest means. Such households might exhaust their resources to marry off a daughter, a practice that also caused upper-class writers to complain, as we see in the following remarks written by Ch'en Hung-mou in the middle of the eighteenth century:

When it comes to marriage, people care only about keeping up with the times. They spend extravagantly on material things. When they present betrothal gifts (p'in ) or make up a dowry (lien-tseng ), the embroidered silks and satins and the gold and pearls are matched one for one. Utensils and articles for the home and business are the finest and the most expensive, and they must be beautifully made as well. The decorated pavilion to welcome the bride and her elegant sedan chair, the banquet where the two families meet and exchange gifts, all require the most fantastic outlays of cash. One sees the worst of this among poorer people, who will borrow heavily to give the appearance of having property, all for the sake of a single public display, ignoring the needs of the "eight mouths" at home. Families with daughters are the most burdened; the families with sons can procrastinate and put off [marriage plans].

Ch'en thought it would be a good idea if everyone limited dowry processions to six chests, an unlikely proposition in an area where twenty chests was apparently de rigueur.[2]

Concern about dowry was only one aspect of the bitter competition for status that pervaded eighteenth-century life. This competition produced an unusual series of conversations about wives and brides in the writings of mid-Ch'ing intellectuals. Their conversations, which appear in a variety of texts (didactic, political, and scholarly), are reminiscent of Victorian writings on the subject of women. Like the Victorians, mid-Ch'ing writers valorized the woman's role as wife, manager, and guardian of the "inner apartments." In fixing the place of wives in the domestic sphere, they also sought to fix the fluidity of social change that threatened to erode the boundaries defining their own respectability. In questioning classical conventions governing women's behavior, they simultaneously reasserted those same conventions. In this essay I shall argue that their conversations about women and marriage were a metonymic comment on larger social issues of mobility and class during the eighteenth century.

The conversations—which I shall call a "new discourse on marriage"—were part of the Confucian revival of the mid-Ch'ing period, a revival that reached down through the ranks of the commoner classes and focused on the family. Among the scholar-elite, "textual research" or "Han Learning" called attention to the original language of ancient canonical works, including marriage rituals and kinship terminology. Even commoners who could bare-


206

ly read were caught up in the revival because of state propaganda campaigns promoting a common ideal of domestic life that emphasized wifely fidelity and service. The state campaigns contributed in turn to a growing interest in compiling genealogies and family instruction books for upper-class households and those newly arrived at respectable status. As a result of these conditions—which affected scholarship, official duties, and personal writing—the elite men who presided over large families were led to ponder and comment anew on the ambiguous position of women in the Chinese family system.[3]

At the heart of the concern about family was the remarkable social mobility, both upward and downward, that marked the mid-Ch'ing era. Evidence for mobility comes from the revival of commerce and the flourishing of trade guilds; from the growth of new literati occupations outside formal government office; from an apparent rise in literacy rates among women as well as men; and from complaints about affluence, conspicuous consumption, and "petty" competition in the literary arts (Ho 1962; Naquin and Rawski 1987:58-59, 114-33). Surely the most striking development with respect to mobility in the mid-Ch'ing era was the series of imperial edicts eradicating the final remaining hereditary class barrier in Chinese society. Beginning in 1723, members of certain occupational and regional groups listed in the household registers as chien, or "debased," were declared eligible for commoner status once they had "purified" their family lines by abstention from polluting work for three generations (Terada 1959). Though the edicts did not eliminate "debased" status groups, I believe the promised emancipation of the lowborn and the intense scrutiny of "pure" blood lines that attended their proposed assimilation into the commoner classes were crucial elements in the changing consciousness this essay examines.

In sum, anxiety about blurred boundaries of all kinds—including the boundaries between "respectable" (liang ) and "polluted" (chien ) women—informed the conversations we are about to explore and gave them special urgency. At stake was not only the purity of marriage markets but also the reproduction of status in a competitive society. Classical revival, moral rebirth, and the unprecedented mobility of women throughout the stratification system prompted enormous concern about how to keep women in their place. Yet these conversations were only partly about women's roles within the family. They were also about marriage and the market: about reaffirming the endogamous marriage markets of the scholar-elite to exclude interlopers, and to distinguish educated women of the upper class from their cultivated sisters in the courtesans' salons. The literati writers of this era identified wives and daughters alike as women who carried forward the status of their families and the honor of their class in the face of threats from all sides.


207

Han Learning and the Recovery of Classical Marriage Norms

The scholars of the Han Learning movement looked to pre-Sung texts for guidance as they sought the "original" pure meaning of Confucian norms and language. Among their rediscoveries was abundant material on the meaning of marriage. The Li chi, the I li, and the Po-hu t'ung, all important Han texts widely cited and read by these scholars, emphasized marriage as a rite of adulthood and stressed the proper preparation and education of women for marriage. A review of these texts will indicate the scope of their appeal in the mid-Ch'ing period.

Han texts describe marriage as a ritual that simultaneously marked the individual's entry into a world of adult responsibility and reconstituted the conjugal fulcrum of family life. As the next generation entered adulthood, moreover, the elder generation prepared to step aside. Even though mourning and burial were ranked higher in the ritual order, and even though a funeral usually cost more than a wedding, marriage was recognized as the "root," or foundation, of all ritual.[4] According to the Li chi (Book of Rites), marriage marked the second of the series of crucial ceremonies in the individual life cycle, following the ritual capping (for boys) and the ceremonial hairpinning (for girls). The "Ch'ü li" (Summary of Rules of Propriety) chapter says: "When one is ten years old, we call him a boy; he goes [out] to school. When he is twenty, we call him a youth; he is capped. When he is thirty, we say, 'He is at his maturity'; he has a wife" (Legge 1967 1:65; LC 1:4b).[5] A later passage, in the "Nei tse" (Pattern of the Family) chapter, elaborates on the significance of this transition to "maturity" at marriage: "At thirty, he had a wife, and began to attend to the business proper to a man. He extended his learning without confining it to particular subjects. He was deferential to his friends, having regard to the aims (which they displayed)" (Legge 1967 1:478-79; LC 12:15b).

The early years of marriage, then, for men marked the expansion of social networks and broad programs of study that prepared them for an official post (the next transition, conventionally said to begin at age forty). Marriage for the elite male was a significant public step toward a career in the larger society. For the upper-class' woman, by contrast, the path leading to marriage steadily contracted her sphere of activities, confining her ever more strictly to the domestic realm. At the age of ten, just as her brothers were leaving the home to attend school, a young girl was cut off from all access to the world outside the home: she "ceased to go out from the women's apartments" and began instructions with a governess who taught her

pleasing speech and manners, to be docile and obedient, to handle the hempen fibres, to deal with the cocoons, to weave silks and shape waistbands, to learn


208

woman's work in order to supply necessary clothing; to be present at the sacrifices, supplying the liquors and sauces, filling the various stands and dishes with pickles and brine, and assisting in setting out the appurtenances for the ceremonies. (Based on Legge 1967 1:479; LC 12:15b)

For the young lady, the counterpart of her brother's capping ceremony was the hair-pinning ritual, which took place at the age of fifteen, to be followed by marriage at the age of twenty to twenty-three years (Legge 1967 1:479; LC 12:16a). At that point, a portentous choice was made: she became a bride if she went through the rites of betrothal, a concubine if she did not (ibid.). Following the elaborate rituals signifying her transfer into the household of another family, the young woman centered her activities in the home of her husband's parents, concentrating her energies on the needs of that household.

We are accustomed to viewing this transition in a young woman's life as the nadir of her life cycle, the point at which she became least powerful, most vulnerable, most isolated, most alienated (Wolf 1972:128-41). Like all aspects of Confucian thought, however, norms governing marriage embodied what Benjamin Schwartz (1959) has called "polarities," and mid-Ch'ing writers were looking to dignify, not degrade, their women. They therefore focused on passages that both sanctioned wifely obedience and subservience and also stressed the dignity and authority of the wife in her new husband's family. A close reading of the Han ritual texts revealed that from the time of her entry into the home of her husband, the bride was ritually marked as his mother's successor. The Po-hu t'ung made this clear in a poignant passage: "The wedding is not [a case] for congratulations; it is [a case of] generations succeeding each other" (Tjan 1952 1:249; PHT 4 shang :255-56). In the Po-hu t'ung, as the groom goes out to meet the bride, his father reflects that the son is soon to replace him at the ancestral sacrifices: "Go and meet thy helpmeet, that [with her] thou mayst succeed me in the sacrifices to the ancestral temple. With diligence lead her, [but also] with respect, [for she is] the successor of thy mother after her death"(ibid.).[6]

Thus, although it is true that a young bride's sphere of activity remained confined to the "inner" domestic realm after her marriage, certain ritual texts nevertheless emphasize the power she acquired, barring misfortune, in her new sphere. It was these texts that caught the eye of status-conscious bride-givers in the mid-Ch'ing era, particularly the chapter on marriage in the Li chi.

The Li chi stresses wifely deference and submission, re. marking frequently on the importance of "obedience," "duty," and "service." At the same time, it offers a view of the marital relationship that emphasizes affection, partnership, and shared responsibility. Affirming the overwhelming importance


209

of finding a suitable wife, the Li chi elaborates on the wife's central role in her marital family. Noting that "the ceremony of marriage provides for the propitious union between two [families of different] surnames" (LC 44:1a), the text explains that the purposes of the bond were, first, to ensure the continuation of sacrifices in the ancestral temple, and, second, to secure the continuity of the family line. The Li chi emphasizes the seriousness and profundity of the rituals surrounding the exchange of information and gifts leading up to the engagement and the ceremonies marking the wedding itself. Part of the ceremony included the ritual eating of the same animal and sipping from cups made from halves of the same melon; this showed, according to the text, "that they now formed one body, were of equal rank, and pledged to mutual affection" (Legge 1967 2:429-30; LC 44:1b).

On careful reading, then, the Li chi could be interpreted to emphasize distinctions and difference more than hierarchy, dominance, or submission. A proper marriage was arranged and celebrated to underscore gender differences and to emphasize the complementary and separate responsibilities of man and woman in the conjugal relationship. Marriage was the primary human social bond demonstrating the "righteousness," or "propriety" (i ), of each distinctive human role. Like all primary relationships, marriage required deference and submission (wives are to husbands as sons are to fathers and subjects to rulers). But the Li chi stressed that husband and wife interact to demonstrate harmony, and it implied that a filial son would learn how to establish a warm and responsible relationship with his father, not by observing his mother's deference, but by watching his parents' loving interaction. A father who abused his wife would invite only his son's resentment and rejection, and a resentful and rebellious son, as everyone knows, makes an unreliable subject. Thus the Li chi revealed how a wife mediates the critical filial bond tying father to son. She was the pivot around which loyal and compliant subjects were socialized (LC 44:1b).

The complementary responsibilities of husband and wife were also summarized in a concluding passage of the "Hun i" ("The Meaning of Marriage") chapter, which explains how, in ancient times, the Son of Heaven took charge of instructions pertaining to the "public and external government of the kingdom," while his wife instructed the palace women "in the domestic and private rule which should prevail throughout the kingdom" (Legge 1967 2:432-33; LC 44:3a). Thus, the regulation and harmony of families was the responsibility of women, just as the regulation and harmony of government was that of men.

The natural basis of this gender division of labor in the governance of public and private spheres was proved by its correlations with the natural world: when the public sphere was in disorder, an eclipse of the sun occurred; when the private realm. was in disarray, the moon was eclipsed. The


210

Son of Heaven, or the queen, as appropriate, had to respond to these portents with purification rituals. Parents of the people, the emperor and empress, were like father and mother, each attending to his or her appropriate concerns (LC 44:3b).

In general, the language of classical texts masked hierarchy in this way, stressing not subordination but complementary spheres and "natural" sequential transformations. A discussion of the relationships among the five elements in the Po-hu t'ung, for example, offered a cosmological explanation for patrilocal marriage. Referring to the relationships among the five ebb-merits, the text says: "The son not leaving his parents models himself on what? He models himself on fire which does not depart from wood. The daughter leaving her parents models herself on what? She models herself on water which by flowing departs from metal" (Tjan 1952 2:442; PHT 2 shang :95). The principle of complementarity between husband and wife was apparent in other sections of the classics. Both the Li chi and the I li describe a particular ritual to he performed on the day after the wedding, dramatizing the importance of the entering bride. The ceremony required the parents of the groom first to toast the new bride. She then toasted them in turn, after which the parents were to leave the room by a door facing west, while the bride departed from the east. Commentators explain that these directions signify that the bride will ultimately take her mother-in-law's place in the family, becoming the woman responsible for carrying on the family line.[7] As a ritual statement, this ceremony followed by one day the rites in which the new bride served her parents-in-law a dressed pig, signifying her obedience.

For the bride, then, rituals expressing obedience were coupled with those emphasizing responsibility and authority. Obedience was critical not only because it upheld the authority of elders but also because it was essential to the harmony of the household; one day the bride herself would have to command obedience from younger women. The text repeatedly notes that the perpetuation of the family line depends on domestic harmony, for which the women who presided over the household were responsible. It is worth noting here that all power consigned to wives in the domestic realm was constrained on every side by fine distinctions of age and status. Teaching women how to use this power became an obsession of mid-Ch'ing scholars, who were drawn to these ritual texts, as we shall see, for reasons of their own.

Constrained or no, the idea of complementarity between spouses so evident in Han texts formed an important theme in mid-Ch'ing scholarly writing on women and the family. It appears prominently in the writings of Yü Cheng-hsieh (1775-1840), well known as a critic of foot binding, widow chastity, and the double standard (Ropp 1981:144-46).[8] A skilled philologist, Yü researched the history of language, which clearly influenced his views on women. In a short note on the historical meaning of the word ch'i (wife), Yü examined in some detail the "egalitarian" interpretation of marriage in


211

Han texts, explaining why the classics could not be invoked to support the subordination of women in marriage and the family (KSTK 4:105-6):

The Discourses in the White Tiger Hall [PHT 4 shang :268] states that ch'i ('wife') means ch'i ('equal'), that is to say, she is equal to her husband. The "Chiao t'e sheng" chapter of the Book of Rites says: "Your husband is the person with whom you stand as an equal [ch'i ] on the platform [of marriage]; you are never to leave him as long as you live." It is from this phrase that the word [wife] derived its meaning.

Now the term fu ('husband') means fu ('to support, to steady, to prop up'). This term originally was a yang [masculine, strong, active] word. The word ch'i ('wife') derived from the word ch'i ('to perch, to settle, to rest for the night'), which is most assuredly a yin [feminine, weak, passive] term.

The "Hun i" chapter of the Book of Rites says: "In ancient times, the emperor had one empress (hou ), three consorts (fu-jen ), nine concubines (p'in ), twenty-seven mistresses (shih-fu ), and eighty-one paramours (yü-ch'i )." The "Ch'ü li" chapter says: "The emperor has an empress (hou ), consorts (fu-jen ), concubines (p'in ), mistresses (shih-fu ), paramours (ch'i ), and lovers (ch'ieh )."[9] It also states that the feudal lords have consorts (fu-jen ), mistresses (shih-fu ), paramours (ch'i ), and lovers (ch'ieh ). In this case, clearly, the term ch'i does not mean "equal."

Confucians have a saying that an imperial paramour (ch'i ) is the same as an imperial lover (ch'ieh ), which they explain is because the term ch'i means "equal." And what are we to make of the "Ch'ü li" passage that mentions paramours and lovers in the same breath?

The term ch'i must be understood in its specific context. It is used by everyone from the emperor to the common people.

In textual research, notes such as these offered no larger analytical or moral message. They nonetheless show us how scholars of the mid-Ch'ing era attempted to recover the consciousness and the values of the past and gave them new life in their writing and thought.

Understanding language in historical context made it possible, for instance, to distinguish the past practices of the imperial household and the ancient aristocracy from the standards that guided the scholar class in the present. Yü's short research note titled "Appellations" ("Ch'eng-ming") (KSTK 4:125) analyzed the classical terms used for affines, notably ego's wife's brothers and ego's sisters' spouses and their sons. The note specifically compared past practice with present custom, indicating that regular social intercourse between intermarrying families, including the brothers of wives and the spouses of sisters, was an important feature of mid-Ch'ing family life. We shall refer again to Yü Cheng-hsieh's textual research and to the complementarity of conjugal bonds when we examine the common interests of intermarrying families in the eighteenth century.

Probably the aspect of Yü Cheng-hsieh's thought that has received the most attention (where it pertains to the status of women) is his critique of the


212

double standard implicit in the ban on widow remarriage—a prohibition that was widely observed among the upper classes of the Ch'ing period (Elvin 1984; Mann 1987). Yü's point of departure for his argument, in the essay "On Chaste Widows" ("Chieh-fu shuo"), was his research on the notion of ch'i (equality, matching) between husband and wife at marriage. He quotes from the "Chiao t'e sheng" chapter in the Li chi: "A match once made should never be broken" (LC 11:13b). This means, he says, that when one's spouse dies, one does not remarry. He concedes that Pan Chao in the Han, so widely cited as the model for young widows of later times, did in fact write that "a husband has a duty (i ) to remarry; for a wife, there is no written prescription for entering a second marital relationship. Therefore, for a woman, her husband is like Heaven [and she can never replace him with someone else]." But confronting this passage, Yü comments:

Although it is absolutely true that no written permission is given for women to remarry, there is at the same time an unwritten assumption that men should not take a second wife. The reason why the sages did not make this standard of conduct explicit in their teachings is the same as the reasoning that underlies the following passage: "The rites do not descend to the common people, nor do punishments reach up to gentlemen." When we make this statement, of course, we do not mean that commoners cannot follow the rites, or that gentlemen will never be punished. By the same token, men who wantonly seek wives just because the meaning of the Book of Rites was not explicitly spelled out are ignoring their true duty. According to the ancient rites, husband and wife were to be honored or despised together, as a single body. But a man sets his wife apart in a lower position when he invokes the ancient phrase "never be broken." He should realize that the "never" refers to both men and women alike. "Casting out a wife for the seven reasons" in fact describes seven ways to break a match; "if his wife dies, a man should remarry" is the eighth way. When the principles and duties of men are so broadly defined and unspecific, it is truly shameful to read so much into a few words and then use them to establish limits on wives alone. (KSLK 13:493)

Classical revival, then, in calling attention to the double standard, emphasized the privileged role of wives. The Po-hu t'ung took great pains to distinguish principal wives from concubines: "The rites forbid the betrothal of a woman as concubine. This means that she cannot be raised [to the position of principal wife]" (Tjan 1949 1:258; PHT 4 shang :264).[10]

There were good practical, as well as moral, reasons why mid-Ch'ing writers were concerned about widower remarriage, and these shall be examined below. The point here, however, is to stress again the impact of classical revival on the views of mid-Ch'ing literati. At every turn, it appears, they were discovering ways to valorize the status of brides and wives in their class and to emphasize the differences that separated marriageable women from concubines and women of lower rank.


213

Female Literacy and Women's Education

The Han Learning movement coincided with a proliferation of guidebooks for educated women, including reprints of the Instructions for Women (Nü chieh ) by Pan Chao, the illustrious female scholar (nü-shih ) of the Han period. (Yü Cheng-hsieh's essay criticizing widow chastity begins by quoting from this important text, underscoring its high visibility in the mid-Ch'ing period.) Interest in women's education followed naturally from classical injunctions requiring special preparation and training for aristocratic young ladies, preferably in the ancestral hall of their descent groups. Women were educated for marriage, and the best education for marriage was training in the Four Attributes (ssu te ) appropriate to wives: proper virtue, speech, carriage, and work (Legge 1967 2:431-32; LC 44:2b).

The connection between moral education and marriage was made explicit by Pan Chao, who used the idea of the Four Attributes to organize her own instruction book. Her text, a training book for wifehood, invoked concepts of complementarity in marriage found in the Li chi. She understood the tao of conjugal relationships to be metaphorically like the "natural" relationships of yin and yang, Earth and Heaven. She valorized marriage by calling attention to the honor accorded it in the Li chi and by emphasizing that it is celebrated by the first ode in the Shih ching. She also criticized views of marriage that stressed only the control of husbands over their wives, noting that though all classical texts portrayed marriage as a reciprocal relationship that depended on the wife's ability to "serve" her husband as well as on his ability to "control" her, both service and control depended on the "worthiness" (hsien ) of each partner. Men, she noted, were educated so that they could understand the foundations of their authority and wield it effectively; women too required education if they were to serve properly in the domestic realm:

Only to teach men and not to teach women—is that not ignoring the essential relation between them? According to the "Rites," it is the rule to begin to teach children to read at the age of eight years, and by the age of fifteen years they ought then to be ready for cultural training. Only why should it not be (that girls' education as well as boys' be) according to this principle? (Swarm 1932:84-85; NC shang :4b-5a)

These views on women's education, and Pan Chao's own eminence as a scholar and intellectual, were taken seriously by scholars of Han Learning during the eighteenth century. Until that time, from the Six Dynasties period through most of the Ming, Pan Chao was probably best remembered as a celibate widow (Swann 1932:51). In the late Ming period, however, interest in female instruction took a new turn. Lü K'un anticipated the concerns of some mid-Ch'ing intellectuals: he was interested in the complementarity of the husband-wife relationship and concerned about educating women as fu-


214

ture mothers and heads of the domestic realm (Handlin 1975:36-38). Handlin, in her analysis of Lü K'un's own instruction book for women, the Kuei fan (Regulations for the Women's Quarters), emphasizes that he was addressing a "new audience" of commoners (min-chien fu-nü ) who "suddenly have three or five volumes in their chests" (ibid., 17).

During the eighteenth century, accessible schooling and rising standards of living expanded the market for books. Commoners attuned to concerns about proper marriage and behavior were avid consumers of works on managing the household. Women were part of this consumer market: literate women were prominent in Buddhist sutra-reading societies and in poetry classes, studying with Yuan Mei and other leading scholars (Ch'en 1928: 257-74).[11]

Concern about female education was mounting, as evidenced by the market for women's instruction books.[12] A compact new edition of basic books, self-consciously styled The Four Books for Women (Nü ssu-shu ), was bound and printed before the middle of the nineteenth century under the editorship of Wang Hsiang, who contributed one of the four works—a collection of his own mother's instructions, the Nü-fan chieh-lu (A Brief Outline of Rules for Women).[13] The other three books were Pan Chao's Nü chieh; a T'ang text entitled Nü Lun-yü (Analects for Women), written by Sung Jo-hua; and the Nei hsun (Instructions for the Inner Apartments), composed early in the fifteenth century by the empress Hsu (Jen Hsiao-wen).

Education for women was the subject of a much-reprinted collection of moral instructions by Ch'en Hung-mou. In the preface to his Repository of Rules for Education of Women (Chiao-nü i-kuei ), Ch'en explained the significance of female education:

The girl who begins as a daughter in your family marries out and becomes a wife; she bears a child and becomes a mother. A wise daughter (hsien nü ) will make a wise wife and mother. And wise mothers rear wise sons and grandsons. The process of kingly transformation [literally, wang-hua, the transformative influence of the ruler on his subjects] therefore begins in the women's apartments, and a family's future advantage is tied to the purity and the education of its women. Hence education is of the utmost importance. (CNIK Preface: 2a)

Clearly, education was for Ch'en the mark that set apart the women of his class—those given and those taken as brides—from everyone else. But what sort of education should women receive? In Ch'ing times, upper-class women were trained in the arts of needlework, poetry, painting, calligraphy, and music-making.[14] Mastery of these arts alone, however, did not mark status, for they were also claimed by professional female entertainers and courtesans. What set apart the marriageable women of Ch'en's class from the rest was moral instruction: education in the ta i, or "ultimate significance," of classical texts.


215

In an essay addressing this subject—significantly, the first of his works to command widespread attention—Chang Hsueh-ch'eng sketched the history of "women's learning," or "women's studies," since ancient times. The earliest women's studies, he argued, were in fact professional curricula that trained women for specific occupations. Thus, female historians studied one body of texts, female soothsayers another, female shamans still another—just as men would select one of the arts for specialized training for a particular office. Later, however, more general studies for women as a gender category developed, and a body of learning proper to females (as opposed to males) emerged. This "women's studies" literature emphasized womanly virtue, speech, appearance, and conduct and linked these to the example and scholarship of Pan Chao.[15]

In Chang's mind, moral education of the sort espoused by Pan Chao contrasted explicitly with training in the arts for professional female entertainers. Chang praised the Manchu government for taking a strong stand on this issue by banning female courtesans from the palace Office of Musicians (Chiao fang ssu) and distancing itself from the patronage and training of female entertainers. To teach women music and poetry without requiring prior rigorous training in the rites—especially the rites of family relation-ships—was to invite loose morals.

The removal of courtesans from the Office of Musicians, which Chang called "the most illustrious act of our august ruling dynasty" to date, loomed large in the minds of mid-Ch'ing intellectuals for another reason: it was the prelude to the general emancipation of debased peoples. The Office of Musicians was originally staffed by a hereditary class of professional entertainers called "music makers" (yueh-hu ), some of whose descendants were already living in isolated communities in north China after being expelled from the palace in a political dispute early in the fifteenth century. The yueh-hu were the first of the major pariah groups named in the emancipation edicts, and scholars specifically linked the abolition of the hereditary court musicians' offices to the end of pariah status for the yueh-hu. Writing more than fifty years later, Yü Cheng-hsieh took the history of the Office of Musicians as his own point of departure for a long essay on the emancipation proclamations (KSLK 12:474-87).[16]

The end of debased-status groups, especially hereditary groups of female entertainers, threatened the integrity of endogamous marriage markets, and with it the very foundation of hierarchy among women.[17] As bearers of the honor and status of their class, marriageable female commoners had to be kept separate from those who were bought and sold.[18] Thus, debates about women's education simultaneously explicated and clarified anew the critical class barriers in this mobile society. One result was the essay by Chang Hsueh-ch'eng that attempted to draw more firmly the lines around the cloistered women's domain by scorning the attempts of some women to join male-


216

dominated poetry arid writing groups. The ending of legal restrictions on debased groups must be seen in the context of a more commercialized society in which status barriers of all kinds were becoming less salient.

Rules for Family Living: Women in the Domestic Group

To serve the new market, in addition to books on women's instruction, guides to family living that addressed wifely roles were printed in affordable new editions or privately circulated among friends. The classic family instruction books composed by Yen Chih-t'ui in the Six Dynasties period (Yen-shih chia-hsun ) and by Yuan Ts'ai in the Sung (Yuan-shih shih-fan ) were rescued from the rare book market and reprinted in the Compendium from the Never-Enough-Knowledge Studio (Chih-pu-tsu-chai ts'ung-shu), bringing their cost within the means of most scholarly families.[19] Reading and rereading these old texts, a few scholars were inspired to compile their own books for the education of their offspring and family members. (We shall examine one such contribution, by Wang Hui-tsu, below.) Interest in advice books went hand in hand with another new fashion: publishing "clan rules" to accompany the genealogies that were at the peak of their popularity during this period (Hui-chen Wang Liu 1959a:71).

Even the so-called statecraft writers of the mid-Ch'ing era tried their hand at essays on family matters. Wei Yuan's classic Collected Writings on Statecraft of Our August Dynasty (Huang-ch'ao ching-shih wen-pien), compiled in 1824-25, devoted an entire chapter (chüan 60) to essays on family instructions (chia chiao ), including the excerpt from Chang Hsueh-ch'eng's "Women's Studies" (Fu hsueh) discussed above.[20] Essays in the section on ritual examine the position of women in the patrilineal family system, especially the problematic ritual place of concubines and successor wives.[21] Domestic relations, particularly the conjugal bond, were not irrelevant to statecraft, if we may judge by Wei Yuan's selections.[22] Finally, the chapter on marriage rites in Wei Yuan's collection begins with an essay on women's education: it was "the foundation of a proper family, the beginning of kingly transformation" (HCCSWP 61:1-2).

Wang Hui-tsu (173l-1807), himself a writer of the statecraft school who published a famous guidebook for administrative aides, wrote his own guide for the domestic realm: a set of family instructions dedicated to his children and titled Simple Precepts from the Hall Enshrining a Pair of Chaste Widows (Shuang-chieh-t'ang yung-hsun). (The title commemorates the two women who were most responsible for shaping his views on such matters: his late father's second wife and his own mother, who was a concubine.)[23] The work is addressed to his sons and grandsons:

Once while I was home nursing an illness, I began reading the Yen-shih chia-hsun and the Yuan-shih shih-fan every day, and I would expound on these texts to


217

my assembled family, to provide them with models for "maintaining their integrity while remaining involved with worldly affairs" [ch'ih-shen she-shih ]. Sometimes I would expound upon the general principles; at other times I would give concrete examples as illustrations. Felicitous words, elegant deeds, and the foundations of day-to-day relationships between teachers and pupils—on each of these subjects, from time to time, I was pleased to offer formal teachings in the Way of proper conduct, which they in turn were to record by hand. Gradually my notes filled a satchel with jottings. I organized the notes that amplified the sentiments in the Yen and Yuan texts into six broad categories, encompassing 219 small items. These I arranged in six chapters.

The first is called "A Record of Those Who Went Before." It commemorates the wisdom of our ancestors, beginning with the events in the life of my late mother and her actual deeds, without repeating anything that has already been written down. The next chapter is called "Regulating the Self." This means, as Confucius once said, being able to follow your natural desires without transgressing what is right. The third chapter is called "Managing the Family." This chapter is limited to the discussion of a fundamental principle: continuing the ancestral line requires the guidance of mothers. Therefore the chapter deals in some detail with women's behavior. The fourth chapter, entitled "Responding to the Times," shows how if one has few occasions for blame, and few for regret, one will be able to rejoice many times over. The fifth chapter is called "Plan for the Future." It shows how to provide security for future generations, and how to sow the seeds of great things to come. The final chapter is entitled "Teachers and Friends," and includes a discussion of relationships in school. (SCTYH Preface:1a-b)

Picking up a theme from both the Yen-shih chia-hsun and the Yuan-shih shih-fan, Wang Hui-tsu examined the intricacies of remarriage and widowhood in a large Chinese family.[24] He lavished special attention on the plight of the widower who must find another mother for his children, a situation well understood in his own household, as his father took a second wife after the first died, though his own mother, a concubine, was still living. What kinds of problems confronted the widower? How irreplaceable was his first wife? And what pitfalls awaited the man who took a second wife instead of contenting himself with a concubine lacking the ritually high status accorded a spouse?

The first answer to these questions appears in a section entitled "Taking a second wife makes it hard to be a father":

Your first wife may not necessarily be wise, but the children she bears will not resent her on that account. In the unlucky event that she dies, however, you may have no choice but to take a successor wife. And if she happens to be unwise, and insists on making narrow distinctions [presumably between her children and others, or between her conjugal interests and those of the larger household], patching up the quarrels that result will be a source of grief for you.

If conditions are optimal and your new wife understands the larger moral principles of family relationships, she will always be unfailingly kind. But even in


218

those circumstances the children of your first wife will look on her as an outsider. And so if you give them instructions or assign them tasks, they will blame all their failure to carry out your orders on their stepmother.

For you, the father, this means that reproof and admonitions to your children will always provoke resentment and jealousy from them; even if you do nothing, you will invite slander from them. Who can be blamed for this situation? (SCTYH 3:2a)

Clearly, the person to blame is the father, for making the mistake of re-marrying. Elevating a second woman to the formal status of mother to all one's children is a step to be taken only at the risk of alienating offspring and losing one's authority over the coming generation.

Wang Hui-tsu commented further on the relationship between stepmothers and their stepchildren in a note entitled "Serving a stepmother":

Even if a stepmother is hard to please, she must be attended to according to the rules of propriety. How much more true this is if your stepmother is easy to please! Even so, we often find that a mother who is easy to please gets a reputation for being hard to please, even to the point where she is being called "narrow-hearted" (pu-i ) and the father is being called "unkind." Now what kind of an attitude is that?

There are exceptions to this pattern. For instance, no one could have been wiser than my [step]mother Lady Wang. Thus, when I was thirteen years of age, she restrained me with orders that were strict and spartan. An agnatic kinsman of my father's generation said to me privately: "Your mother treats your younger sister far more kindly than she treats you." I denied this passionately, and thereafter I listened to her instructions more diligently than ever. Within four years, my kinsman's son was dead, and a little over ten years later, he himself died. Now his descendants are also dead, and this causes me to wonder whether his words may not still be having an effect today. (SCTYH 3:2a-b)

A stepmother, we see here, easily became the object of gossip and slander among kinsmen. Her commitment to her stepchildren was ambivalent, and that ambivalence could readily be turned against her by gossip that alienated her spouse's offspring. Few stepsons, we may imagine, were as loyal to their stepmothers as the young Wang Hui-tsu.[25]

If the hapless widower chose not to remarry to avoid these problems, he only faced new ones. The plight of one unfortunate soul, in a large household full of conjugal units devoted to serving their own needs, is outlined in a section titled "In serving a widowed father or mother, one must be even more attentive than ever":

A widowed mother has her sons' wives to rely on and daughters to wait on her—although the sons' wives will have their own children, and the daughters their husbands arid in-laws as well, so a widow cannot depend exclusively on


219

her own children; if she is ill, or in pain, or hungry, or thirsty, she may have no one to complain to.

But how truly desolate is the father who is old and living alone! Recently I visited an elderly kinsman who had lost his wife in middle age, and who had been sleeping and eating alone well past his eightieth year. He said to me: "My handkerchief has been ruined for a long time, and I've been trying to get another one, but I can't." And so saying, he began to weep. I was greatly distressed by this, and I went to report it to his sons. They paid no attention. Not long after, his sons too went the same route, poorer than he. The mirror of Heaven is close at hand—isn't it fearsome! (SCTYH 3:2b-3a)

Each of Wang's homilies makes clear the intractable complications stemming from the death of a first wife in households that observed Confucian family norms. The father who remarried to ensure care and companionship in his old age risked rebellion or alienation from his children; fathers shielded their children from the wiles of a stepmother at the price of a solitary and lonely retirement. Clearly, however, in mid-Ch'ing times this was the price they were expected to pay.

Further discussion of the problems involving first and successor wives, from a slightly different perspective, appeared in Ch'en Hung-mou's Repository. Though the classics taught women that "one's husband is one's Heaven," in reality a wife had to serve three heavens: her father-in-law, her mother-in-law, and her spouse (CNIK hsia :22b). Her primary duty there was to encourage him to be completely filial to his parents: "the full realization of filiality begins with the wife." But remarriage complicated the relationship between mother-in-law and daughter-in-law. For example, remarriage posed the possibility that a daughter-in-law might "distinguish between the first and the second." A "successor wife," that is, a woman who took the ritual place of a deceased first wife, might not command the respect of her status-conscious daughter-in-law. On this account, successor wives were warned to take care to be "polite" to their stepsons' wives, and daughters-in-law were enjoined never to make any distinction between the "first" and the "second" by such nasty little signs as passing through doorways first. Families were cautioned to watch for telltale signs of insubordination and correct the wayward daughter-in-law's thinking immediately (ibid., 24a).

These "petty distinctions" among women (widely decried as the source of all discord in Confucian families) could be drawn still more finely in cases where the daughter-in-law, as a ritually sanctioned first wife (shih-hsi ), served a mother-in-law who was herself a concubine (shu-ku ). In such cases, the advice to the daughter-in-law was clear: "You may not presume upon your status as first wife to slight a concubine" (pu-k'o shih shih man shu ) (CNIK hsia :24b).

Ch'en's Repository therefore recognized that status-conscious (i.e., well-


220

educated) brides could not he counted on to abandon their class consciousness within the confines of the domestic sphere. And if they were hard on mothers-in-law, they were even worse when it came to servants. Wives took out their frustration, their boredom, and their jealousies on their servants because propriety forbade striking relatives or even children. In fact, physical abuse of servants was so common among women of the upper classes that one text in the Repository supplies detailed descriptions of types of abuse as a warning to readers. Servants, by their conduct and appearance, offered a living testimony to the faults of an abusive mistress: "One may enter her home, observe her servants, anti know whether she is a good wife or not" (CNIK hsia :1a-5a.) The Repository admonished its female audience that servants were not "a different order of being, like dogs or horses," but human. It stressed that scholars and commoners could not own slaves, though slaves were still employed in government service. Instead, male servants in commoner households were called "adopted sons" (i-nan ) and female servants "adopted daughters" (i-hsi, or i-nü ), to signify that they were "just like family members." They were to be so treated: well clothed, well fed, never abused (ibid., 1a-5b).

If young women with servants could be abusive, they could also be lazy. Sloth was a blot on the character of any bride, an all-too-common sign that she had abandoned one of the four cardinal womanly attributes. Young ladies who grew up waited on hand and foot never learned how to manage properly their role as mistress of the family servants and keeper of the household account books. Unlike wives in poor families—"busy all day, reeling thread, cooking food, drawing water, pounding rice, minding the farm, serving their mothers-in-law, suckling babies, generally working to exhaustion" (CNIK hsia :14b)—the women who circulated through the marriage markets of the rich were spoiled, above all, by servants. Nursemaids took care of their children; maids and concubines even did their needlework! "All they have to think about is making themselves beautiful. Everything is done for them, so they don't know that rice comes from a stalk and silk is unreeled from cocoons. They treat money like dirt, and living creatures like bits of straw" (ibid., 15a).

Problems with household servants could be mitigated through fictive kin ties and prolonged association. But relations with women of low status outside the household were always dangerous. Every instruction book contained warnings about the "hags" whose marginal occupations gave them access to the cloistered inner apartments—female physicians, religious adepts, go-betweens, peddlers, nuns.[26] Wives had to be taught to "maintain strictly the separation of the inner domain from the outside world," lest they become the victims of gossip and manipulation by threatening females from outside who would "turn their hearts astray" (CNIK chung :4a).

Repeated admonitions about the "six hags" reveal anxiety about female


221

mobility and about defining boundaries around women. Women's religious practice, and the corrupting influence of the religious—not only nuns but also monks and priests—worried Ch'en Hung-mou, who wrote about the need to cloister women in an essay reprinted in the Collected Writings on Statecraft (HCCSWP 68:5b):

A woman's proper ritual place is sequestered in the inner apartments. When at rest, she should lower the screen [in front of her]; when abroad, she must cover her face in order to remove herself from any suspicion or doubt, and prevent herself from coming under observation.[27] But instead we find young women accustomed to wandering about, all made up, heads bare and faces exposed, and feeling no shame whatsoever! Some climb into their sedan chairs and go traveling in the mountains. . . . We even find them parading around visiting temples and monasteries, burning incense and holding services, kneeling to listen to the chanting of the sutras. In the temple courtyards and in the precincts of the monasteries, they chat and laugh freely. The worst times are in the last ten days of the third lunar month, when they form sisterhoods and spend the night in local temples; and on the sixth day of the sixth month, when they believe that if they turn over the pages of the sutras ten times, they will be transformed into men in the next life.

The text goes on to condemn the monks and priests who seduce these mobile women in much the same tone reserved for the nuns and other "hags" who serve as liaisons between cloistered females and the outside world.

Again, concerns about women traveling abroad to monasteries were not new in the eighteenth century. But in the larger context of a mobile society, where competition for status was being promoted on many levels by action of the state, an obsession with boundaries in the writings of mid-Ch'ing scholars assumes a heightened significance. Concern about boundary crossing in the domestic realm, I would suggest, was a metaphor for concern about boundaries in the society as a whole. Within the scholar class, female literacy was breaking down the walls that separated the sexes and kept women pure from the contaminating influences of the outside world. In the society at large, mobility was eroding occupational and class barriers that had once served to segregate marriage markets. Though women were the focus of much of the anxiety that attended these changes, in the discourse we have examined, women became a vehicle for expressing concerns about status shared by all men of the scholar class.

Conclusion

That wives and marriage were a focal point in a discourse about class and mobility is hardly surprising. As in Renaissance Venice, nineteenth-century France, and colonial Mexico, marriage in mid-Ch'ing China was a contract that aimed above all at reproducing class structures.[28] State law, and the


222

system of moral beliefs we call Confucianism, sanctioned norms governing marriage, and thereby protected the existing class hierarchy. However, those sanctions cut two ways: they could protect class-endogamous marriage markets, or they could undermine them. The discourse on marriage that emerged during the mid-Ch'ing period points to the ways in which the boundaries around sacrosanct marriage markets were being challenged. As the state moved to loosen status distinctions, Confucian morality was invoked to shore them up. Writers of the period show us, in their extended conversations about women and class, how the combined effects of affluence, literacy, and mobility threatened to destroy the conventions that lent stability and order to social life. Their conversations also remind us that codes lodging the honor of class and family in pure women were not confined to the shores of the Mediterranean. During periods of rapid social change, in China as elsewhere, women were named the guardians of morality and stability, charged with protecting the sanctuary of the family.

At the same time, as we have seen, women themselves posed part of the challenge to social order. Their literacy, their religiosity, and their own strivings for comfort and security helped to provoke the mid-Ch'ing discourse on marriage. What we know now about this discourse is based on what men said and wrote. But the time will come when we will be able to see beyond men's interests and show how women construed their own roles in the dramatic changes of the mid-Ch'ing era.[29]


227

Glossary

Chang Hsueh-ch'eng inline image

Ch'en Hung-mou inline image

ch'eng-minginline image

ch'i (equal) inline image

ch'i (paramour) inline image

ch'i (to perch) inline image

ch'i (wife) inline image

chia chiaoinline image

Chiao fang ssu inline image

Chiao-nü i-kueiinline image

"Chiao t'e sheng" inline image

"Chieh-fu shuo" inline image

ch'ieh (concubine) inline image

ch'ieh (lover) inline image

chieninline image

Chih-pu-tsu-chai ts'ung-shuinline image

ch'ih-shen she-shihinline image

"Ch'ü li" inline image

fu (husband) inline image

fu (to support) inline image

Fu hsuehinline image

Fu hsueh san tseinline image

fu-jeninline image

houinline image

hsieninline image

hsien nüinline image

Hsu (Jen Hsiao-wen) inline image

Huang-ch'ao ching-shih wen-pieninline image

"Hun i" inline image

iinline image

i-fuinline image

i-hsiinline image

I liinline image

i-naninline image

i-nüinline image

Kuei faninline image

k'uei-ssuinline image

Li chiinline image

lianginline image

lien-tsenginline image

Lü K'un inline image

min-chien fu-nüinline image

Nei hsuninline image

"Nei tse" inline image

Nü chiehinline image

Nü-fan chieh-luinline image

Nü lun-yüinline image

nü-shihinline image

Nü ssu-shuinline image

Pan Chao inline image

p'in tse wei ch'iinline image

p'in (betrothal gifts) inline image

p'in (concubine) inline image

Po-hu t'unginline image

pu-iinline image

pu-k'o shih shih man shuinline image

Shih chinginline image

shih-fuinline image

Shih hou-mu inline image

shih-hsiinline image

shu-kuinline image

Shuang-chieh-t'ang yung-hsuninline image

ssu teinline image

Sung Juo-hua inline image

ta iinline image

taoinline image

tso-huiinline image

Wang Hsiang inline image

wang huainline image

Wang Hui-tsu inline image

WeiYuan inline image

yanginline image

Yen Chih-t'ui inline image

Yen-shih chia-hsuninline image

yininline image

Yü Cheng-hsieh inline image

yü-ch'iinline image

Yuan-shih shih-faninline image

Yuan Ts'ai inline image

yueh-huinline image

yung-mieninline image


228

References

Primary Sources

Chao I inline image. Kai-yü ts'ung-k'aoinline image. c. 1775; reprint, Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1957.

CNIK Ch'ung-k'an chiao-nü i-kueiinline image, comp. Ch'en Hung-mou inline image. 1895 edition.

CPTC Chih-pu-tsu-chai ts'ung-shuinline image, comp. Pao T'ing-po inline image. 1823; reprint, Shanghai: Ku-shu liu-t'ung-ch'u, 1921.

HCCSWP Huang-ch'ao ching-shih wen-pieninline image, comp. Wei Yuan inline image. Preface dated 1826; reprint, Taipei: Kuo-feng ch'u-pan-she, 1963.

Ho Chu inline image. 1973. "Yung-su sang-li so-chi" inline image. In Ning-po hsi-su ts'ung-t'aninline image, ed. Chang Hsing-chou inline image. Taipei: Min-chu ch'u-pan-she.

IL I liinline image. Ssu-pu pei-yao edition.

KSLK Kuei-ssu lei-kaoinline image, by Yü Cheng-hsieh inline image. 1833; reprint, Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1957.

KSTK Kuei-ssu ts'un-kaoinline image, by Yü Cheng-hsieh inline image. 1833; reprint, Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1957.

LC Li chiinline image. Ssu-pu pei-yao edition.

NC Nü chiehinline image, by Pan Chao inline image. Reprinted in Nü ssu-shuinline image. Shanghai, 1893-94 edition.

PHT Po-hu t'unginline image. Ts'ung-shu chi-ch'eng edition, vols. 238-39.

SCTYH Shuang-chieh-t'ang yung-hsuninline image, by Wang Hui-tsu inline image. Preface dated 1794; reprint, Taipei: Hua-wen shu-chü, 1970.

YSCH Yen-shih chia-hsuninline image. n.d.; reprint, CPTC , vol. 11.

YSSF Yuan-shih shih-faninline image. Preface dated 1788; reprint, CPTC , vol. 14.

Secondary Sources

Arrom, Silvia Marina. 1985. The Women of Mexico City, 1790-1857. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Ayscough, Florence. 1937. Chinese Women: Yesterday and Today. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.

Bourdieu, Pierre. 1976. "Marriage Strategies as Strategies of Social Reproduction." In Family and Society: Selections from the Annales, Economies, Sociétiés, Civilisations , ed. Robert Forster and Orest Ranum. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Cahill, James. 1967. Fantastics and Eccentrics in Chinese Painting. New York: The Asia Society.

Ch'en Tung-yuan inline image. 1928. Chung-kuo fu-nü sheng-huo shihinline image (A. history of the lives of Chinese women). Shanghai: Commercial Press.

Chojnacki, Stanley. 1975. "Dowries and Kinsmen in Early Renaissance Venice." Journal o f Interdisciplinary History 5.4:571-600.

Ch'ü, T'ung-tsu. 1961. Law and Society in Traditional China. Paris: Mouton.

Chung, Priscilla Ching. 1981. Palace Women in the Northern Sung, 960-1126. Leiden: E.J. Brill.

Ebrey, Patricia. 1981. "Women in the Kinship System of the Southern Song Upper


229

Class." In Women in China , ed. Richard Guisso and Stanley Johannesen. Youngstown, N.Y.: Philo Press.

———. 1984. Family and Property in Sung China: Yüan Ts'ai's Precepts for Social Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

———. 1986. "Concubines in Sung China." Journal of Family History 11.1:1-24.

Elman, Benjamin. 1984. From Philosophy to Philology: Intellectual and Social Aspects of Change in Later Imperial China. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Elvin, Mark. 1984. "Female Virtue and the State in China." Past and Present 104:111-52.

Handlin, Joanna F. 1975. "Lü K'un's New Audience: The Influence of Women's Literacy on Sixteenth-Century Thought." In Women in Chinese Society , ed. Margery Wolf and Roxane Witke. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Harrell, Stevan, and Sara A. Dickey. 1985. "Dowry Systems in Complex Societies." Ethnology 24.2:105-20.

Ho Ping-ti. 1962. The Ladder of Success in Imperial China: Aspects of Social Mobility, 1368-1911. New York: Columbia University Press.

Hu Wen-k'ai inline image 1956. Li-tai fu-nü chu-tso k'aoinline image (A review of women's writings throughout history). Rev. ed., Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1985.

Hummel, Arthur W., ed. 1943-44. Eminent Chinese of the Ch'ing Period. 2 vols. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

Hyland, Alice R. M. 1987. Deities, Emperors, Ladies and Literati: Figure Painting of the Ming and Qing Dynasties. Birmingham, Ala.: Birmingham Museum of Art.

Jones, Susan Mann, and Philip A. Kuhn. 1978. "Dynastic Decline and the Roots of Rebellion." In The Cambridge History of China: Late Ch'ing, 1800-1911 , ed. John K. Fairbank. Vol. 10, p. 1. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Ko, Dorothy Yin-yee. 1989. "Toward a Social History of Women in Seventeenth-Century China." Ph.D. diss., Stanford University.

Kulp, Daniel Harrison. 1925. Country Life in South China: The Sociology of Familism. New York: Columbia University Teacher's College.

Legge, James, trans. 1967. Li Chi: Book of Rites. 2 vols. New Hyde Park, N.Y.: University Books.

Liang Ch'i-ch'ao inline image. 1955. Chung-kuo chin-san-pai-nien hsueh-shu-shihinline image (Intellectual history of China during the last 300 years). Taipei: Chung-hua shu-chü.

Liu Chi-hua inline image. 1934. "Chung-kuo chen-chieh kuan-nien ti li-shih yen-pien" inline image (The historical transformation of the concept of chastity in China). She-hui hsueh-chieh 8:19-35.

Liu, Hui-chen Wang. 1959a. "An Analysis of Chinese Clan Rules: Confucian Theories in Action." In Confucianism in Action , ed. David S. Nivison and Arthur F. Wright. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

———. 1959b. The Traditional Chinese Clan Rules. Locust Valley, N.Y: J. J. Augustin. Mann, Susan (see also Jones, Susan Mann). 1985. "Historical Change in Female Biography from Song to Qing Times." Transactions of the International Conference of Orientalists in Japan 30:65-77.

———. 1986. "Shapers of a Common Culture: Moral Education under Qing Rule." Paper presented at the University of California, San Diego. October.


230

———. 1987. "Widows in the Kinship, Class, and Community Structures of Qing Dynasty China." Journal of Asian Studies 46.1:37-56.

Morohashi Tetsuji inline image. 1957-60. Daikanwa jiteninline image (Great Chinese-Japanese dictionary). 12 vols. Tokyo: Taishukan shoten.

Naquin, Susan, and Evelyn S. Rawski. 1987. Chinese Society in the Eighteenth Century. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Nivison, David S. 1966. The Life and Thought of Chang Hsüeh-ch'eng (1738-1801). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Parish, William L, and Martin King Whyte. 1978. Village and Family in Contemporary China. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Rankin, Mary Backus. 1975. "The Emergence of Women at the End of the Ch'ing: The Case of Ch'iu Chin." In Women in Chinese Society , ed. Margery Wolf and Roxane Witke. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Ropp, Paul. 1981. Dissent in Early Modern China: Ju-lin Wai-shih and Ch'ing Social Criticism. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Schneider, Jane. 1971. "Of Vigilance and Virgins: Honor, Shame and Access to Resources in Mediterranean Society." Ethnology 10:1-23.

Schwartz, Benjamin. 1959. "Some Polarities in Confucian Thought." In Confucianism in Action , ed. David S. Nivison and Arthur F. Wright. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Steele, John, trans. 1917; reprint, 1966. The I-li, or Book of Etiquette and Ceremonial. Taipei: Ch'eng-wen.

Stolcke, Verena. 1981. "Women's Labours: The Naturalisation of Social Inequality and Women's Subordination." In Of Marriage and the Market , ed. Kate Young, Carol Wolkowitz, and Roslyn McCullagh. London: CSE Books.

Swann, Nancy Lee. 1932. Pan Chao: Foremost Woman Scholar of China. New York: Century.

Terada Takanobu inline image. 1959. "Yoseitei no semmin kaihorei ni tsuite" inline image (The emancipation of the debased people during the Yung-cheng reign period). Toyoshikenkyu 18.3:124-41.

Tjan, Tjoe Som. 1949, 1952; reprint, 1973. Po Hu T'ung: The Comprehensive Discussions in the White Tiger Hall. 2 vols. Westport, Conn.: Hyperion Press.

Wang Shu-nu inline image. 1933; reprint, 1988. Chung-kuo ch'ang-chi shihinline image (A history of prostitution in China). Shanghai: Shang-hai san-lien shu-tien.

Wolf, Margery. 1972. Women and the Family in Rural Taiwan. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Yü Ying-shih. 1975. "Some Preliminary Observations on the Rise of Confucian Intellectualism." Tsing Hua Journal of Chinese Studies 11:105-46.


231

Seven
Wives, Concubines, and Maids
Servitude and Kinship in the Hong Kong Region, 1900-1940

Rubie S. Watson

Anthropologists and historians have often written about the household as if it were a social actor with its own set of unquestioned goals, interests, and survival strategies. In study after study scholars have granted the household a single, unified voice; a voice, it should be noted, that is nearly always male. In recent years, this approach has come under increasing criticism (see, e.g., Dwyer and Bruce 1988; Hartman 1981; Rapp 1978; Thorne and Yalom 1982; Yanagisako 1984). In the China field Margery Wolf's work on the uterine family (1972) and Myron Cohen's discussion of women's private property (1976:164-91) clearly demonstrate that their informants' households were made up of different constituencies whose goals and ambitions were often at odds. The interests of women and men did not always coincide, nor, they argue, did all household women share the same agenda.

In the following pages I discuss the ways in which servile status and gender inequality interact to create conditions of subordination and hierarchy within the household itself. I argue that the inequality among household men differs from that among household women and that these differences are related to the overall structure of gender and class inequality. In what ways, I ask, are wives, concubines, and maids affected by gender and class stratification, and how do their ties to the household and family differ from one another and from coresident males? The reference point for this study is, as Robertson and Klein point out in their discussion of slavery and gender in Africa, at the "intersection of intra- and extrafamilial stratification" (1983:18).

In this paper I examine the status of wives, concubines, and "little maids" in the Hong Kong region from 1900 to 1940. The households discussed in this paper tended to be large, including concubines, slaves, indentured menials, and servants as well as three or four generations of family members. Some entered the household through birth or marriage while others arrived

Versions of this paper were presented at the American Anthropological Association Annual Meeting, Washington D.C. (1985), the Department of History Colloquium Series, University of Pittsburgh (1986), and at the Working Class History Group, University of Pittsburgh (1988). I am grateful for the comments I received on those occasions. I am especially indebted to Patricia Ebrey, Stevan Harrell, and James Watson for their assistance in revising this paper.


232

via a more circuitous route involving China's enormous market in people. Within a single household, attachments might involve relations between employer and employee, master and servant, owner and owned, debtor and lender.

In the households described in this paper, membership was highly fluid; there was, in fact, considerable turnover in both family members and their retainers. Furthermore, clear distinctions among people living in the same household were not always easy to make; servants, including servile menials, were often spoken of as kin, and kin were sometimes treated as servants. Within the households of the wealthy there was, however, one group who maintained a clearly demarcated and unambiguous position. These were men who through birth or adoption had shareholding rights in the family estate and, like their fathers and grandfathers before them, expected someday to assume the role of household head (chia-chang ). Bound by ties of agnation, these men and boys had claims and attachments to the household and family that their sisters, who were destined to leave the communities of their birth, did not. Rights to residence, property, and placement in the ancestral cult clearly distinguished the household's male servants and slaves from the chia chang and his agnates.

If unambiguous boundaries could be drawn between groups of household men, what distinguished household women? In a recent article Patricia Ebrey has argued that in Sung China clear distinctions can be made between women related to the household head through ties of kinship and marriage and those "menial women" who entered the household through purchase, debt, or wage employment (1986:2, 6).[1] If "family women" were indeed different from coresident, menial women, in the period under discussion here, how did they differ? Can the same variables we use to distinguish household men be used to classify household women? In Chinese society, women as a category had a dependent status. In a recent article, Hill Gates argues that Chinese women suffered from a kind of sociocultural invisibility (1989:813). Before marriage they were under the control of their fathers; after marriage they were dependent on their husbands, and if they outlived their spouses, they fell under the jural authority of their sons. Their kinship status was ambiguous. Women, Margery Wolf points out, are only temporary sojourners in their father's households, and even at marriage their integration into their husband's family is only partial (1972:32-37; see also R. Watson 1981:610-611; 1986). Writing of the patrilineal family in rural Taiwan, Wolf comments that the bride is an outsider who serves the family of her husband but remains beyond its formal boundaries (1972:35). Chinese women could not inherit in their own right the family estate of their father or their husband; nor did they have shares in ancestral or lineage property (see Shiga 1978:110, 120). When considered against the standards of their brothers and husbands, it is clear that women were not equal partners in what Gates


233

labels the "patricorporations" of late imperial China (1989:805) or, for that matter, in the wider society of which they were a part. If women did indeed stand outside the formal property-holding family, it would appear that economic criteria are not sufficient to distinguish among household women. Categories of men can be demarcated according to whether they had rights to material assets; with women the situation is more complicated.

Among household women there are two groups in particular—concubines (ch'ieh )[2] and "little maids" (in Cantonese, mui jai )—that defy easy categorization. Among a household's "unfree population,"[3] they came closest to assuming a kin role. There were, of course, important differences between the two; maids fell more easily within the servant category than did concubines, who participated more fully in the life of the family. Both groups of women, however, shared a marginal status that makes them difficult to classify.

If concubines and mui jai present problems of classification, how do they compare to the wives and daughters of the families they served? I have already noted that wives and daughters were not full shareholders in the family estate, nor did they wield the kind of authority and power that was the prerogative of the household head. Neither, it should be noted, could they aspire, like their brothers and husbands, to the status of chia chang. In the realm of family authority and property, therefore, it appears that categories of women are not as easily distinguished as are those of men. The situation is different, however, if we look to other factors.

Wives and daughters were responsible for the daily care of the household's ancestors and gods; concubines and maids had no such responsibility. Daughters left the household and wives entered it with considerable ceremony; the entries and departures of concubines, maids, and other menials were perfunctory, involving little or no ritualization. Wives had a claim on descendants' attention in the afterlife; menial women had none. These are important differences, but further distinctions can be made.

In order to understand how gender inequality affected household relations, we need to know more about the lives of the women. How did wives, concubines, and maids enter the household? Did they retain ties to their natal families and did their entry create new kin ties for their husbands, brothers, and future offspring? Are we right in assuming that all women were equally alienated from the family estate? The answers to these questions will help us to better appreciate the complex links between gender inequality and other forms of subordination.

Concubines and little maids were found throughout China but this discussion focuses on a Cantonese-speaking area of southeastern China.[4] Because British colonials took a keen interest in the mui jai population and conducted a number of investigations into their status, there exists a substantial literature on the mui jai problem in Hong Kong.[5] I rely in particular on one report published in 1937 by a specially constituted colonial commission (hereafter


234

referred to as Report 1937); this publication, it should be noted, summarizes earlier investigations and recommendations. In 1977-78 and again in the summers of 1985 and 1988 I conducted fieldwork in the single-lineage village of Ha Tsuen in Hong Kong's New Territories. The material I collected there, both interviews and documentary data, have also been utilized in this analysis. During my fieldwork I was able to interview women who either had been served by mui jai or had themselves been mui jai or concubines.

While I was writing this chapter, Maria Jaschok's book, Concubines and Bondservants: The Social History of a Chinese Custom , was published. In a series of life histories, Jaschok concentrates on the experience of specific concubines and maids, providing rich detail on their personal backgrounds and the effect those had on their roles within the households they joined. Jaschok's book and this chapter, which seeks to examine concubines and maids in relation to the wives and daughters among whom they lived, provide each in its own way evidence of the class, status, and gender divisions that permeated the inner courts of many Chinese households.

Markets in People and Services

In the late imperial and Republican periods it was not uncommon for domestic servants and even industrial workers to have their labor coerced by ties of debt bondage or involuntary indenture (see, e.g., Honig 1986; Hershatter 1986; J. Watson 1980b). It is important to see mui jai and concubines within the context of this market in people. According to James Watson, until 1949 "China had one of the largest and most comprehensive markets for the exchange of human beings in the world" (ibid., 223). The forms of bonded and slave labor were highly variable. Joseph McDermott's discussion (1981) of bondservants highlights the complicated array of servile labor forms during the Ming period (1368-1644). Unfortunately, we have as yet no comprehensive studies that plot the trajectory of slavery and bondage during the late imperial and Republican periods. There are enormous gaps in our knowledge of the changing patterns of bondage in China. To what extent did the history of male and female bondage differ or converge? Were the bonds that held women different from those that enslaved or indentured men? Were females more likely to be pawned or sold than males?

In Hong Kong's New Territories during the Ch'ing, male slaves (hsi min ), whose status was inherited through the male line, were attached to many wealthy households. With their emancipation at the time of the Republican Revolution in 1911, however, male slavery ceased to exist as a viable institution in this area (see J. Watson 1980b:245). Pawning and indenture, nevertheless, continued to be part of the labor scene until World War II, and women, it would appear, were well represented, perhaps overrepresented, among Hong Kong's unfree population.


235

In recent years scholars have argued (see, e.g., Robertson and Klein 1983; Clinton 1982) that in Africa and the southern United States the prevailing systems of gender inequality and of servitude interacted in complex ways to affect the lives of the free and unfree of both sexes. In the view of some students of sub-Saharan Africa, slavery itself was subsumed by the sexual division of labor and gender subordination. Many scholars of the antebellum South believe slavery perpetuated and strengthened gender discrimination and an ideology of female dependence (for a critical discussion of this view see Lebsock 1984). In China we have yet to appreciate the interaction between inequalities based on gender and those based on servitude. Detailed studies of slavery and indenture, domestic service, and labor contracts in late imperial China are necessary if we are to adequately address this interactive process.

In an 1879 sentencing of five people accused of kidnapping and selling children in Hong Kong, Sir John Smale, a Supreme Court justice, noted that two forms of "slavery" continued to be well represented in the colony. One was domestic servitude (presumably referring to mui jai ) and the other was the acquisition of women for purposes of prostitution (Report 1937:123). Smale estimated Hong Kong's "slave population" in the 1870s to be 10,000 (out of a total population of 150,000). If I am correct in assuming that Smale's category of domestic slavery refers to mui jai , it seems likely that the vast majority of Hong Kong's servile population were girls and women. Andrea Sankar, an anthropologist who studied domestic servants in Hong Kong, points out that in the early 1900s mui jai constituted the majority of nonfamily labor in local households (1978:53). Evidence will be presented in this paper that suggests mui jai were present in substantial numbers until World War II.

A little maid (or mui jai , literally "little younger sister") is defined in the Hong Kong Commission Report of 1937 as "a girl who has been transferred from her own family, either directly or through a third party, to another family with the intention that she . . . be used as a domestic servant, not in receipt of regular wages and [not] at liberty to leave her employer's family of her own free will or at the will of her parent" (Report 1937:22). The definition concludes by noting that there was usually a document giving the details of the transfer and the "consideration passing" between parents (or mui jai dealer) and master.[6] The term of service was seldom specified, but it was expected that the master or mistress would marry off the mui jai when she was eighteen or so. It should be noted that little maids entered their master's household at the age of eight or nine years. At marriage the servant's obligation to her master ended and she was said to become a free person. Some households apparently failed to free their mui jai , keeping them indefinitely in their servile status. There are also indications that at least some masters resold their mui jai (see, e.g., Jaschok 1988:8, 45, 70, 72).[7]


236

In a 1922 report prepared by relief societies, the number of mui jai in Hong Kong was estimated at 10,000 (Report 1937:157; see also Jaschok 1988:87, 106). Whether this figure simply repeats Sir John Smale's estimate for 1879 or is in fact an accurate reflection of mui jai numbers in 1922 is difficult to determine at this point. Although the acquisition of new mui jai was prohibited by Hong Kong law in 1923 (Report 1937:159, 126), many local Chinese continued to incorporate little maids into their households, insisting these girls were really adopted daughters. In 1929 a formal register of mui jai was established and left open for six months; anyone possessing an unregistered mui jai after the closing date was considered to be in violation of the ordinance (ibid., 216). By June 1, 1930, when the register was sealed 4,252 mui jai had been recorded. The governor of Hong Kong hailed the registration a success and maintained that the previous figure of 10,000 mui jai had only been a guess. This was not the end of the debate, however. The Hong Kong Census of 1921 listed 8,653 mui jai , and many believed that the number of maids could not have declined so precipitately in the nine years after the census—a period, it should be noted, during which the general population was steadily increasing. Many knowledgeable sources claimed that many more mui jai (10,000-12,000) were living in the colony and chided the authorities for their weak enforcement of the registration provision (ibid., 216-17). In fact, the Chinese press during this period declared that the proportion of mui jai was increasing rather than decreasing (ibid., 216).

Although mui jai were most often found in the households of the urban middle and upper classes, they were by no means restricted to the cities. Rural shopkeepers and rich peasants could and did avail themselves of mui jai labor. In Hong Kong's hinterland (which includes the village of Ha Tsuen where I conducted research in 1977-78) I was told that mui jai were to be found in a number of village households prior to World War II. Unfortunately, there are no published estimates of the number of mui jai living in Hong Kong villages, but they were considered to be a normal part of the households of the rich (see J. Watson 1980b; R. Watson 1985:104). According to Ha Tsuen residents, mui jai worked as household servants in their village until 1951 when the last "little maid" left her master's house to become a concubine of a childless peasant.

Like mui jai , concubines (ch'ieh ) were to be found in the households of the well-off, but their functions were, of course, different. Chinese concubines were recognized sexual partners who lived in their mate's household and whose offspring were legitimate. Legally a Chinese man could have only one wife (ch'i ), and a concubine therefore had a lower social status than the wife (Shiga 1967; for Sung period see Ebrey 1986). In contrast to wives, concubines were not endowed with property when they moved to their consort's household; their families received no betrothal gifts and the concubines themselves received no dowries. Perpetuating the male line was the only re-


237

spectable reason for taking a concubine, although this stricture was often ignored among the wealthy (for a general description of concubinage see Goody 1976:91; 1983:76). Concubines continued to have a legal status well into the Republican period on the Chinese mainland (see Lang 1946:118), and in Hong Kong they enjoyed legal protection until 1971, when laws were written forbidding unions with concubines (Evans 1973:22).

Surveys on the incidence of concubines in early twentieth-century China present conflicting results. According to Buck's 1930s survey data, concubines made up only 0.2 percent of family members in all of China (1937:367; for figures on Taiwan see Pasternak 1983:56-57). Other scholars working on specific populations, however, report significantly higher rates. According to Olga Lang, who conducted a survey of 1,700 high school and college students in the 1930s, 11.4 percent of the students reported that a concubine lived in their family (1946:220-21). This survey covered ten cities in north, south, and central China and apparently focused on middle- and upper-middle-class families (1946:x). Lang's material supports the commonly accepted view that concubines were most likely to be found among the wealthy (on this point see also C. K. Yang 1959:84; Eberhard 1962:130, 188; Lang 1946:39, 220). Sidney Gamble's work in a rural county near Peking and Martin Yang's research in Shantung also confirm the association with wealth. In a survey conducted during the 1920s, Gamble found that the rates of concubinage were "one in 18 for the families with over 100 mu [of land], but only one in 183 for the families with less than 50 mu " (1954:38). Yang reports that the Shantung villagers he studied in north China during the 1930s objected to concubinage even if a wife proved barren, and accordingly he found no concubines in the farming community of Taitou. Yang believes that both poverty and "social tradition" explain the lack of concubinage (1945:114).

My own research in Ha Tsuen and Baker's work in the New Territories community of Sheung Shui (1968:141) underline the link between wealth and political influence on the one hand and concubinage on the other. In the hamlet where I resided, there were three concubines still living in three separate households (out of a total of twenty-three households, 1977-78 data).[8] Two of these women were the concubines of important village leaders, and one belonged to a local businessman. Although Baker provides no overall figure for Sheung Shui as a whole, he found that twelve of the village's thirty-one elected representatives maintained a concubine in the early 1960s (1968:141).

Data from Hakka villages in rural Hong Kong and from the sericulture areas of the Pearl River Delta suggest that although economic status was an important factor in concubinage, wealth is not sufficient to explain it in every case. Both Elizabeth Johnson (1976:175) and Jean Pratt (1960:155) found concubines living in the poor Hakka communities they studied. And in Shun-


238

te County, northwest of Hong Kong, Marjorie Topley found that "concubinage appears to have been widespread among tenant farmers as well as wealthier landowners" (1975:77).

Janice Stockard, in her recent book on marriage patterns in the Pearl River Delta, describes an extremely interesting form of concubinage and marriage in which wage-earning brides (often workers in the local silk industry) married, but chose not to live with, their "husbands." Such a woman, who was recognized as ch'i (in Cantonese as daaih pouh ), paid a lump sum of money to her husband's family, which was used to purchase a concubine (Stockard refers to such women as "secondary wives"), who then took up residence with the husband. Children born of such unions accepted their father's wife, not their concubine mother, as their daaih ma , or "great mother." According to Stockard, such an arrangement had the advantage of securing the appropriate status of wife and mother to the ch'i , without the usual loss of economic independence. Such unions were especially important in safeguarding a woman's position in the afterlife; the husband's family incorporated the tablet of the wife (ch'i ) into their domestic ancestral cult at her death (1989:48-69). Stockard points out that many "secondary wives" were former mui jai (1989:29, 66).

The communities studied by Johnson, Pratt, Topley, and Stockard share a pattern of male outmigration and reliance on women's labor (both in agriculture and in wage work). Whether these two factors alone or in combination with other forces produced the forms of concubinage we find in this area remains to be seen. At this point it seems unlikely that concubinage can be explained by a single set of economic or social factors. What is clear is that concubines were a feature of many Chinese households, and that in such households women from vastly different backgrounds and often with very different goals were forced to interact.

Unfortunately, detailed studies of the "women's quarters" in elite households are rare in the China field.[9] Jaschok is one of the few historians to pay attention to the inner household world of women. Her work dramatically points up the conflicts that emerge when women from different backgrounds are thrown together by decisions made by others. It has often been overlooked that clashes between the values and attitudes of, for example, an ex-prostitute concubine and an upper-class wife were likely, and perhaps even inevitable. Jaschok captures the cultural divide between these women when she writes of the concubine Xiao-li: "Unhindered by female models of passive acquiescence, toughened by material deprivation in her childhood and the need for survival against all odds, trained by a shrewd and worldly woman, Xiao-li was no 'frog in the well' . . . but a calculating strategist who quickly realized where her source of power and strength would lie and how to utilize it" (1988:25; see also 27-28, 32). Jaschok argues that within the household, women faced women as rivals "for emotional hold over 'key' males" (ibid., 24).


239

Mode of Acquisition: Wives, Concubines, and Maids

The entry of wives, concubines, and maids into a household was marked by a transfer of money. The way people thought about and discussed these transfers, however, differed significantly. The language of gifts and reciprocity was used for wives; the idiom of the marketplace was used for concubines and maids.

The wife (or ch'i ) went through a complicated set of rites before entering her husband's family (for detailed descriptions of these rites see Freedman 1967; R. Watson 1981). First, a formal betrothal took place, after which the bride's family was presented with money and food gifts. On the wedding day the bride was carried with great fanfare from her parents' house to the groom's village in a red sedan chair; in present-day Hong Kong a decorated Mercedes-Benz is used. Upon arriving at her new home, the bride worshiped her husband's ancestors. A marriage feast was held on the evening of the wedding day, and that night the marriage was consummated. On the final day of the marriage festivities food gifts (in Hong Kong a roast pig, sugar, and tea) were presented to the bride's family, signifying, my informants told me, the full acceptance of the bride as wife and daughter-in-law.

In marrying a wife, the transfer of gifts and money was sometimes one-sided—from groom's family to bride's. But the bride's family always made some return to the groom's side. Rich families gave substantial dowries to brides (see Dennerline 1986; Ebrey 1981; R. Watson 1981), but even among the poor the bride did not enter her husband's house empty-handed. At the very least, she would be accompanied by a few small pieces of jewelry, clothes, a chest, and some household articles. During my fieldwork in Ha Tsuen, village women stressed that a bride must bring something into the marriage lest she be labeled a concubine.

A concubine entered her master's household quietly, without any fanfare or ceremony. In fact, she was positively enjoined from traveling to her new household via the red sedan chair, which only the ch'i could use (see, e.g., Jamieson 1970:45-46; M. Yang 1945:113; Stockard 1989:30; Report 1937:13). Writing of the Hong Kong village of Sheung Shui in the early 1960s, Baker notes: "Concubines are frequently taken with no ceremony at all" (1968:50). The term mai (to buy) was used to describe the acquisition of a concubine; in most cases she was purchased outright for life (see J. Watson 1980b:232; for discussion of this point in earlier periods of Chinese history see Ebrey 1981:125; 1984:136; 1986:7). Concubines may have been purchased from a brothel (e.g., C. K. Yang 1959:84; Jaschok 1988:14), from dealers in concubines and maids, or from her parents (e.g., Freedman 1979:99). As already noted, Stockard points out that concubines in the Pearl River Delta were often ex-mui jai (1989:29; see also Topley 1975:77; Meskill 1979:226). Ideally concubines, like wives and unlike maids, were acquired for purposes of reproduction, although as I have already noted many men took con-


240

cubines for their own pleasure or perhaps (as among the nouveau riche) to enhance their status.

In most cases, the only ceremony that a concubine performed on entering her master's household was the formal serving of tea to the principal wife. The concubine then assumed a recognized place in her new environment, and, significantly, children born to her while she resided in her master's house were deemed legitimate. According to the Ch'ing legal code, and later during much of the Republican period, the children of concubines had the same rights as those of the principal wife (van der Sprenkel 1962:15; Lang 1946:118; for Hong Kong see Evans 1973:22). Although it is true that the offspring of concubines were the legal heirs of their fathers, the mothers themselves usually were women from poor families or servile background. Their status, as I note above, was therefore well below that of the households they entered. In social reckoning they were clearly inferior to their consorts, their consorts' families, and even their own children, although as I have already noted such women were not necessarily powerless (see, e.g., Jaschok 1988:49, 59).

Maids, like concubines, were purchased. Unlike concubines who served for life, however, maids (at least in the Hong Kong region) were expected to serve only a limited period, usually until age eighteen or so. Once they were married, they ceased being servants—their part of the "bargain" having been fulfilled. Because their time of service was limited by the obligation of the master to marry them off, mui jai were more like indentured servants than slaves (see Report 1937:22). But for all practical purposes the mui jai was treated as if she "belonged" to her master. She generally had no contact with her parents and was usually married with the master, not her parents, acting as guardian. In fact, according to Ch'ing law a master was legally responsible for finding husbands for his female servants; failure to fulfill this obligation carried a punishment of "eighty blows" or a fine (Jamieson 1970:43). Like a daughter, the mui jai 's procreative life was supposed to start only when she left her master's house.

In Hong Kong a 1923 ordinance stipulated that if mui jai or their parents wished to be reunited and the secretary for Chinese affairs made no objection, the mui jai could be restored without a payment to the master (Report 1937:159). But such cases were rare. In the period of the 1930s, when information about reinstatement was most highly publicized, only fifty-two cases of restoration were recorded. According to the report, these involved, in almost equal proportions, instances in which the master, the mui jai herself, or her parents requested the change (Report 1937:168). When we consider that the mui jai population was more than four thousand (by some estimates ten thousand) during this period, and further that no restitution need be paid to the master, the small number of restorations suggests that in most cases the link between mui jai and their parents was not strong.


241

The evidence suggests that many parents severed their ties to or lost contact with their mui jai daughter once she was handed over to her master.[10] This was not inevitably the case, however. Jaschok describes cases of ex-mui jai who did search out and reestablish links to their natal families. The fact that these examples involved particularly forceful concubines who had effectively usurped the position of the wife or had been the recipient of their consort's largess may well be significant. These restorations were not always smooth, however; Jaschok describes one case in which a concubine was forced to pay off members of her family in order to keep them from creating a public nuisance outside her consort's stately mansion (1988:28-30).

The obligation to marry off the mui jai was often used as a rationale for arguing that these servants were really adopted daughters. But the villagers of Ha Tsuen claimed there was a clear difference between the bridewealth or dowry due a daughter and a mui jai. The latter, I was told, received only token marriage payments (see also Stockard 1989:29). In fact, village women still denigrate those they dislike by saying that their enemies' dowries were "as small as a mui jai' s." People in rural Hong Kong also use the phrase "married like a mui jai " to warn their children of the disgrace they would invite by failing to perform the basic set of marriage rites. Stockard's informants recalled cases in which even mui jai who married as principal wives were forced to use plain, wooden sedan chairs rather than the usual red ones (1989:30). Clearly, the stigma of being a mui jai did not disappear with marriage.

Relations to Husbands, Consorts, and Masters

Both wives and concubines were brought into the household as sexual partners and producers of heirs, but wives were expected to manage domestic tasks, while concubines were themselves managed. Although legally, at least, a concubine's offspring had the same status as the children of the principal wife, it was not unknown for a concubine's children to suffer discrimination and banishment either at the hands of their father or, more often, at the instigation of their half brothers once their father was out of the way (see, e.g., Meskill 1979:221; Johnson 1976:175; Jaschok 1988:38). In the village of Sheung Shui, Baker notes that in contrast to the sons of wives, adopted sons and concubines' sons required special validation rites (1968:49).

Maids were clearly servants. There is considerable evidence, however, that masters sometimes had sexual relations with mui jai. If children were born of such unions, it was left to the father to accept or reject paternity. Unlike the European pattern where legitimacy was defined by marriage sanctioned by the church, in China a father could legitimate his children simply by recognizing them publicly at naming rituals (man yueh ) or at lineage/community rituals (k'ai teng ) celebrating the birth of sons (see R.


242

Watson 1985:106-16; Freedman 1979:118). A maid, it should be noted, did not become a concubine or wife simply by bearing her master's children (see, e.g., Meskill 1979:230; Jaschok 1988:70).

Whereas the concubine and wife were linked to their consort by a recognized sexual tie, the mui jai might have had little to do with males in the household. As domestic servants, they fell under the effective control of the household's senior women. In fact, mui jai benefited women far more directly than men, for mui jai took over many of the chores that otherwise would have fallen to daughters and wives. Thus, although men may have been the "owners" of mui jai , women were their effective masters.

The literature suggests that a man could "sell" both his wife and his concubines (see, e.g., McGough 1976:126-27; J. Watson 1980b:231-32; for earlier periods see Ebrey 1986:11, 12). For example, he could pawn his wife or give her away in payment of a debt (for examples see Hershatter and Ocko in this volume). It appears that among the Chinese in British Malaya, mui jai were safeguarded against such transfers, but in Hong Kong they seem not to have enjoyed this protection. It is ironic indeed that wives and concubines may have been more vulnerable to pawning and resale than indentured servants.

Family Ties: Wives, Concubines, and Mui Jai

Quite by accident, when I was conducting fieldwork in 1977 I met the son of an ex-mui jai who had served one of Ha Tsuen's wealthiest families. This former mui jai , now a middle-aged woman living in a public housing estate in urban Hong Kong, continued to make formal New Year visits to her master's family in Ha Tsuen. In this regard she was unusual. To my knowledge she was the only mui jai among the six or more who had served this family to return for yearly visits. There was nothing unusual, however, about her marriage. In dramatic contrast to the daughters of the family she served, she had been married to an extremely poor man and her living circumstances were far from comfortable.

The kin status of concubines is perhaps more complex than that of wives or maids. Obviously, they were members of their consort's household, but to what extent were they incorporated into his family? As noted earlier, a concubine's first act upon moving into her master's house was to make a formal offering of tea to the principal wife. This rite of deference appears to have established the concubine in her master's household, marking the union as something more than a fleeting liaison. In Chinese society, it should be noted, concubines had a recognized status, whereas a mistress had none (see Report 1937:16; R. Watson 1985:111-12). Compared to the public and often elaborate marriage rites that marked the incorporation of a wife, the recogni-


243

tion of the concubine was basically a private, household affair involving only the principal wife and the concubine.

Upon entering a household, concubines were often renamed by their consort or perhaps by his wife (see, e.g., Jaschok 1988:148; for a Sung example see Ebrey 1986:17). Sometimes the concubine was addressed by her name or by a kin term with the diminutive prefix sai (a Cantonese term meaning "small" or "little"). In Hong Kong the son of a concubine often addressed his mother as "little mother" (sai ma in Cantonese) and the son of a principal wife might address his father's concubine as sai jieh (literally "little elder sister"). As anyone who is familiar with Chinese society knows, however, the use of a kin term does not necessarily imply kinship. Those who use such terms confer respect, claim intimacy, or mark the superiority/inferiority of the speaker. The term for younger sister (mui ), which clearly alerts the listener to the fact that a superior is addressing an inferior, is made positively demeaning by the addition of jai , which translates as "little" or "diminutive." The same holds true, although perhaps less dramatically, for "little mother" or even "little elder sister."

Among Cantonese the rules governing the extent to which individuals are obliged to mourn various kin are taken very seriously. If a concubine has a son, he is obligated to mourn his biological mother for a requisite three years after death; however, no one else in the family is expected to mourn her. If at the time of her death the concubine has not produced heirs, no one is obliged to mourn (see, e.g., Shiga 1967:552-53). As for members of the concubine's natal family, there is no indication that they have any mourning responsibilities at all. Thus, the treatment of the concubine after death suggests that the biological tie between mother and son is upheld, but her status within her consort's and her natal family is in fact negated.

A concubine was not supposed to be directly involved with her consort's parents, nor was she allowed to worship his ancestors (Ch'ü 1961:125); these privileges were reserved for the wife. Furthermore, many lineages had regulations against listing concubines in written genealogies (see, e.g., Eberhard 1962:47; Meskill 1979:327 n. 20; Hui-chen Wang Liu 1959:90). In Ha Tsuen concubines' names were added to genealogies only if they produced male heirs (cf. Harrell 1985:83; Tsui-jung Liu 1975:16, 20). Baker reports a similar situation for Sheung Shui (1968:50).

Concubines who failed to produce sons could find themselves in a precarious position. The two New Territories families from whom I rented houses in 1969-70 and 1977-78 both had a history of serial concubinage. Neither of these families aspired to literati status, but in both cases the father of the present household head had taken in four or five concubines over a period of about thirty years. When they failed to produce sons, I was told by neighbors, the concubines were forced to leave or ran away. Whether they were


244

"resold," no one knew or would tell me. In each case one concubine, the last of the series, remained permanently in the family. One of these women raised an adopted son and the other eventually gave birth to a son.

When a woman became a concubine she entered a private, domestic sphere. She was cut off from the outside world and became enmeshed in the private domain of her consort and his household. Her situation was similar to that of a wife, albeit more circumscribed. A wife had links to kin outside her husband's family; these relations gave her a recognized position among her husband's kin and in the wider community. Her father and brothers safeguarded her position, and the status of her natal family helped to determine her own status as she entered her husband's household. Older women in Ha Tsuen put great store in the dowry they received and the manner in which their parents celebrated their betrothals. A concubine did not enjoy these associations and the protection they afforded.

Writing of concubines in Japanese-occupied Taiwan (1895-1945), James McGough quotes an adage that leaves little doubt about how local peasants viewed the disposition of a daughter who had been sold to others: "After you've sold a [daughter], you can't even call out [her] name. After you've sold a field, you can't even have access to its frontage" (1976:30). McGough argues that the sale of a daughter as a concubine implies the severing of her kin ties to her natal family (1976:29). Although, as Jaschok points out, some concubines did reestablish ties to their natal kin (see above), the evidence suggests that in most cases concubines tended to exist at the periphery of the world of family and kinship (cf. 1988:31-32, 76). Without kin, with little or no public (extradomestic) recognition of her role, with no dowry or bridal gifts to secure her status, the concubine bordered on being a nonperson.

Although concubines were not themselves kin, their children were accepted as members of their consorts' families. The offspring of concubines had social fathers, but did they have social mothers? Principal wives created matrilateral kinship for their offspring, concubines did not. A concubine's offspring were born into a recognized kin status within their father's family, but their father's wife, not the concubine, was seen as their formal mother. It seems likely that a concubine's sons, except in special circumstances, were denied the advantages and protections that matrilateral kin might provide. Writing of concubines' offspring in Africa, Meillassoux points out that they "were legally 'sons' and 'daughters,' whose social condition was weak because they lacked a maternal lineage" (1983:57).

In China the children of concubines may have suffered from a "weak social condition" not only because they lacked matrilateral kin but also because their biological mothers had no dowry, nor were they likely to have private funds (ssu-fang ch'ien ) to bestow upon them.[11] In Ha Tsuen a mother's dowry and private fund may have been used to help educate a son or marry off a daughter; business ventures and extras such as tutors, schoolbooks, uni-


245

forms, special trips, and special foods might also be funded by a mother's ssu-fang ch'ien. In a study of lineage development in Wu-hsi, Jerry Dennerline shows that a mother's dowry might be instrumental in preserving the economic interests of a son after the death of his father (1986:190-93). There is no doubt that a woman's dowry could create decided advantages for her children. To be without such maternal beneficence was no small matter. The children of a concubine, therefore, partook to a certain degree of their biological mother's marginality. Concubinage, it would appear, created differences not only among the women of a household but also among its children.

Because maids, like concubines, were bought, was their kin status likely to resemble a concubine's? Many Chinese justified their purchase of mui jai as charity, arguing that it was better for these girls to become "little younger sisters" than to run the risk of starving or being sold into brothels. In some cases affection developed between the mui jai and her master's family, but there was no disguising her servitude. The mui jai received no wages. She was housed, fed, and clothed by her master, who was not supposed to mistreat her or kill her, but other than that he appears to have had full control over her.

Whether most parents signed contracts that turned over full rights to their daughter once they accepted the master's payment is unclear at this point. A thorough search of available contracts is necessary before this issue can be settled with any certainty. We do know that many contracts specified that the fate of the mui jai was "the will of Heaven," which suggests that her parents retained no rights to her and could not serve as her protectors once the contract went into effect (for contract language see Jaschok 1988:146-49). It should be noted, however, that some contracts specified a conditional transfer. A girl's parents "might transfer her as a pledge for a loan, the girl's services being regarded as interest on the loan, on repayment of which the girl would be restored to the parents" (Report 1937:22; see also Stockard 1989:28-29). In these cases the arrangement resembled pawning more than indenture or slavery.[12]

Colonial authorities were under considerable pressure from the antislavery forces both in Hong Kong and abroad to do something about the mui jai problem (see, e.g, Report 1937:151-55, 161; Smith 1982). But local officials clearly felt they were dealing with a deeply entrenched customary practice (Report 1937:162); a simple outlawing of the practice, they argued, was futile. In any event, it is also clear that they were unwilling to take the necessary and, one might add, costly steps that would have eradicated the practice. For example, they balked at establishing agencies to house and find alternative employment for the girls who would have been thrown on the streets had the provisions against the mui jai system been enforced. They also hesitated to require proper wages for girls who would have been converted


246

from mui jai into paid domestic servants had the system been banned. In 1929 a regulation went into effect stipulating that mui jai from ten to fourteen years of age were to be paid $1 per month and those over fourteen years were to receive $1.50 (Report 1937:167; see also Jaschok 1988:103-4). There was no effective oversight machinery, however, to see that even these small sums were in fact paid.

In dealing with the maidservant question colonial authorities were at pains to understand, some might say explain away, the payment made to the mui jai 's parents by her master. In 1923 it was decreed that the payment did not confer any rights of property over the mui jai (Report 1937:159). It was further stated that this payment was similar to a loan that the mui jai 's parents could repay whenever they wanted and thus regain control over their daughter. But the formal declaration had little effect on actual practice in Hong Kong. According to a minority report of the 1937 Commission (published as an appendix) these provisions were laws in name only.

To this point I have concentrated on the mui jai during her years as a servant, but what of her status once she married and escaped her master's house? I have already noted that mui jai tended to marry (with only token marriage payments) poor men or widowers or become concubines.[13] Like concubines, mui jai tended to be estranged from their natal kin, which in later life often meant they were unable to create affinal ties for their husbands or matrilateral ties for their children. Their small dowries may have also put their children at an economic disadvantage. It should be noted, however, that unlike concubines, ex-mui jai wives did have some dowry and could (if they had the resources) maintain their own ssu-fang ch'ien. If a mui jai was fortunate enough to be taken as a principal wife, she enjoyed some advantages over a concubine. As wives (ch'i ), they could become the domestic managers of their husband's household, and, perhaps most important, they were formally recognized as the mother (both social and biological) of their children. Nevertheless, owing to their lack of natal kin, they must have found it difficult to attain the same status as wives who had never been mui jai. Thus, even in adulthood a mui jai could not escape her servant past.

Conclusion

In this paper I argue that wives, concubines, and maids are differentiated by the mode of their incorporation into the household of their husband or master. Concubines and maids were sold and were thus incorporated into their master's household with few or no links to the outside world. We have seen that while concubines and mui jai share a number of characteristics, their situations differed markedly in some important respects. Because concubines served for life, they tended to be less capable than mui jai of ever attaining any real independence. Mui jai could, after all, expect to achieve emancipation


247

through a proper marriage, although many simply exchanged one servile situation for another as they moved from servitude to concubinage.

Taken on a case-by-case basis, some concubines undoubtedly enjoyed decidedly better living conditions than mui jai. Through force of personality or favoritism a concubine might become a powerful household figure effectively usurping the position of the wife herself. Jaschok provides some dramatic examples of such strong-willed and powerful women (see, e.g., 1988:31-32, 48-50). However, the institutional impediments that limited the concubine's freedom of action were indeed great. Among these impediments, perhaps the greatest was the concubines' inability to produce kinship. Writing of a successful concubine, Jaschok observes that her master gave her money and gifts but withheld "the protection and support needed to build up a position of dignity and recognition." Seen from the outside, Jaschok continues, the concubine "had acquired membership of a respected and wealthy family, but from the inside, she remained an outcast on the domestic periphery" (1988:31-32). The cruel and unscrupulous concubine is part of Chinese folklore, but the mirror image of the concubine as victim is also a familiar tale. It is perhaps this latter representation that comes nearer to capturing the experience of many women.

As both Jaschok and Stockard show, a concubine could become a mere extension of the wife. As her reproductive capacities were appropriated by the "great mother" and the patriline she served, the concubine lost her own identity in that of her mistress and rival (see Jaschok 1988:76; Stockard 1989:48-69). This point was most vividly expressed to me by one of my Ha Tsuen informants as she proudly showed me her "son's" wedding picture. My informant (a daaih ma whose husband had fathered five children by his concubine), the bridal couple and the groom's father had pride of place in the photograph. After a careful inspection of the photo, I found the concubine mother standing to one side and behind the crush of bride's parents, siblings, and their children. For me the photo revealed the bitter irony of the wife-concubine dilemma; neither my informant nor her husband's concubine could achieve the only meaningful role available to a village woman—that of wife and mother. Neither was complete according to local notions. The wife came closest to unifying the two feminine functions, but she did this at the expense of the self-effacing, nameless concubine. For the proud daaih ma this must have been indeed galling, but for the concubine it spelled a lifetime of humiliation, dependence, and marginality.

Social identity and social personhood, we are told, depend on one's kin status. Most definitions of slavery stress that a slave could not marry, was not allowed to have a normal family life, and in effect lacked the endowment of kinship (for a discussion of this point see J. Watson 1980a). If slavery is an inherited status, Chinese concubines and maids were not slaves, but shared with them a marginal kin status and were in this sense less than full persons.


248

In Chinese society kinship has economic, political, social, cultural, and personal significance. To be without kin in a society absorbed by kinship was no small matter. Kin ties define, integrate, locate, and socialize the unformed, undefined, and unregulated. Because of their ambiguous kin status, mui jai and especially concubines lived at the edge of the social world. Once they were transferred to their master, mui jai appear to have existed without parents or siblings (without kin in fact). If she were fortunate enough to be taken on as a ch'i , however, the former mui jai gained the right to be both. a recognized wife and mother. The concubine was denied even this—once she entered her consort's household she appears never to have regained her kin status.

Although mui jai and concubines did not pass on their status to their children, their offspring were liable to suffer social handicaps not imposed on the children of a wife (that is, a ch'i who had never served as a mui jai ). Their lack of matrilateral kin and of a mother's dowry may have created disadvantages for offspring, especially those born into elite families. In households where the children of concubines were competing for favor and resources with the children of wives, it would hardly be surprising to find nuanced but nevertheless important differences in their education or marriage opportunities. If we consider concubinage from this point of view, it would seem that the conditions creating a second-class status for the concubine may also have affected her offspring.

Chinese society may provide an exception to the commonly held view that to be a social person, one must be legitimately mothered as well as lathered (see, e.g., Fortes 1969:261). Jack Goody has argued, for example, that "kinship is everywhere bilateral" (1983:16). There is some question, I believe, as to whether the sons and daughters of mui jai and concubines are legitimately mothered. This is especially true of concubines whose children are full heirs yet lack a social mother who can produce or provide matrilateral kin.[14] It may be argued that the children of concubines achieve their personhood solely through their fathers. The extent to which they suffer any personal disadvantage owing to the circumstances of their birth remains an intriguing question.

It seems hardly worth noting that concubines were unmarried. However, this easily overlooked fact is an important element in their ambiguous kin status and in the social marginality they, as a group, were forced to endure. In Chinese society marriage marked the most important transition in a woman's life. Marriage, Stockard writes, was the path to spiritual security for Chinese women (1989:49). As Ha Tsuen villagers say, "a daughter is just passing through," waiting, presumably, to assume her true and proper role as wife and mother. Until she married, a Chinese woman had no resting place either in this life or the next. If she failed to marry, her natal family was often loath to support her, preferring to send her to a nunnery, a brothel, or into


249

domestic service. If she died before she became a wife, her spirit was transformed into a dangerous and unsettled ghost. A Chinese concubine suffered the stigma that attached to all adult women who had no recognized place in society. She belonged neither to the family of her parents nor to that of her consort. She bore, in fact, the double burden of being a woman who was both unmarried and sexually active.

As I note in the introduction of this chapter, Ebrey (1986) has argued that concubines are best understood when they are categorized not as a kind of wife but as a menial. It may be useful to push this argument further by placing the discussion of concubinage (and mui jai status) in the context of gender inequality and servitude. In late imperial and Republican China there were many forms of servitude, and it is likely that further analysis will show that these differences are often related to gender. There is already evidence that in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries girls and women who served as domestic servants were more likely to be involuntarily tied to their work than were male servants, at least in some areas of China. Sankar, for example, points out that most domestic servants in Hong Kong were mui jai or indentured laborers (1978). In a discussion of Taiwanese servants, the historian Johanna Meskill found substantial differences between male and female domestics during the late nineteenth century. Male servants, she writes, "had contracts that stipulated pay and customary bonuses." She adds that "the bulk of the maid servants were indentured, entering the Lin household around the age of eight and serving, without pay, for about ten years" (1979:230). Further investigations may show that in the early twentieth century the system of gender and class inequalities created a situation in which girls from poor families were more vulnerable to pawning, sale, and involuntary indenture than were males of similar socioeconomic status.

We already know that in China, as in many other peasant societies, servile women often ranked below servile men. McDermott shows that during the Ming, male bondservants could join free men in exchanging women. Referring to a sixteenth-century contract, McDermott describes the case of a penniless man who was promised his subsistence and a wife (a maid in the master's household) in return for twenty-two years of indentured labor. Offspring from this marriage were "contracted, before birth, to serve their father's master, and a daughter would have to stay 'as compensation' on the termination of the father's contract" (1981:681, emphasis added). Here we have a case of master and male bondservant deciding the fate of women who were obviously their dependents. "The women in these male transactions," McDermott writes, "amounted to little more than objects of sale" (ibid., 681). There is some justification for thinking that no matter what the status group, Chinese women ranked below and were in some way dependent on men.

The two categories of servile women discussed here had an ambiguous


250

relation to the families they served. Concubines and mui jai are said to have been like family members, yet their status was not clearly defined. One suspects that such ambiguity would not have been tolerated for an enslaved or indentured male servant. The ideology of patriliny is particularly strong :in the Pearl River Delta, where there are clear and rigid boundaries between agnates and nonagnates. These boundaries restricted access to crucial resources, reserving them for a defined group of agnates; membership in the patrilineal kin group determined rights to landed estates, political brokers, and protection in an often violent environment. In a society where women did not inherit family property and were considered to be of little political consequence, there was no pressing need to clarify the kin status of a maid or concubine. Thus, the boundaries that separated servile men from free men were likely to prove far more rigid than those that delineated servile women from free women (see also Robertson and Klein 1983; Meillassoux 1983:56; J. Watson 1980b:249; Wright 1983:249). Whether this made male servitude harsher than female servitude requires further analysis. What is clear is that late imperial and Republican China were societies in which gender inequality significantly affected patterns of servitude.

Although I argue that the boundary between free (but dependent) women and servile women was less clear than the boundary between free and unfree men, it is important to note that in Chinese society the position of wife could be clearly distinguished from that of concubine or mui jai.[15] Wives and daughters played a role in household and family rituals denied to concubines and mui jai. Wives had a publicly recognized role both inside and outside the family. They had the status of legitimate kin and could provide their offspring with matrilateral ties. They were also property holders, although their relation to property lacked clear legal sanctions (see Ocko in this volume).

Although a wife might not have enjoyed the legal protections granted her brothers or husband, the possession of a dowry was an important economic expression of the differences that set her apart from concubines and maids. Although women may have been categorically alienated from full membership in the family estate and although their legal rights to dowry were ill defined (see the chapters by Ebrey and Ocko and afterword in this volume), ch'i were not without property altogether. In fact, one might say that the dowry, and the property-holding status it legitimated, was a defining characteristic of wifely rank. It is perhaps ironically fitting that in late imperial and Republican China the status of wife was contingent on such a tenuous hold over what were often minuscule amounts of property. Compared with men, all women were less than full members of their families, but wives occupied a privileged position denied to concubines and maids. Thus, the capacity to produce kinship anti the ability to command dowry set "free women" apart from the mui jai and the concubines who served them.


251

Glossary

Terms marked (C) are in Cantonese and those marked (H) are in Hokkien; all other terms are in Mandarin.

ca-bo-kan (H) inline image

ch'iinline image

chia-changinline image

ch'iehinline image

daaih ma (C) inline image

daaih pouh (C) inline image

jai (C) inline image

maiinline image

man yuehinline image

muinline image

mui (C) inline image

mui jai (C) inline image

sai (C) inline image

sai je (C) inline image

sai ma (C) inline image

sai pou (C) inline image

ssu-fang ch'ieninline image

References

Baker, Hugh. 1968. A Chinese Lineage Village, Sheung Shiu . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Buck, John Lossing. 1937. Land Utilization in China . Nanking: University of Nanking Press.

Ch'ü, T'ung-tsu. 1961. Law and Society in Traditional China . Paris: Mouton.

Clinton, Catherine. 1982. The Plantation Mistress: Woman's World in the Old South . New York: Pantheon.

Cohen, Myron. 1976. House United, House Divided: The Chinese Family in Taiwan . New York: Columbia University Press.

Dennerline, Jerry. 1986. "Marriage, Adoption, and Charity in the Development of Lineages in Wu-hsi from Sung to Ch'ing." In Kinship Organization in Late Imperial China, 1000-1940 , ed. Patricia Buckley Ebrey and James L. Watson. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.


253

Dwyer, Daisy, and J. Bruce, eds. 1988. A Home Divided: Women and Income in the Third World . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Eberhard, Wolfram. 1962. Social Mobility in Traditional China . Leiden: E. G. Brill.

Ebrey, Patricia. 1981. "Women in the Kinship System in the Southern Song Upper Class." In Women in China , ed. Richard Guisso and Stanley Johannesen. Youngstown, N.Y.: Philo Press.

———. 1984. Family and Property in Sung China: Yüan Ts'ai's Precepts for Social Life . Princeton: Princeton University Press.

———. 1986. "Concubines in Sung China." Journal of Family History 11:1-24.

Evans, D. M. Emrys. 1973. "The New Law of Succession in Hong Kong." Hong Kong Law Review 3:7-50.

Fortes, Meyer. 1969. Kinship and the Social Order: The Legacy of Lewis Henry Morgan . London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

Freedman, Maurice. 1967. Rites and Duties, or Chinese Marriage . London: G. Bell & Sons.

———. 1979. "Colonial Law and Chinese Society." In The Study of Chinese Society: Essays by Maurice Freedman , ed. G. William Skinner. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Gallin, Rita. 1984. "Rural Industrialization and Chinese Women: A Case Study from Taiwan." Journal of Peasant Studies 12.1:76-92.

Gallin, Bernard, and Rita Gallin. 1982. "The Chinese Joint Family in Changing Rural Taiwan." In Social Interaction in Chinese Society , ed. S. L. Greenblatt, R. W. Wilson, and A. A. Wilson. New York: Pergamon Press.

Gamble, Sidney. 1954. Ting Hsien: A North China Rural Community . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Gates, Hill. 1989. "The Commoditization of Chinese Women." Signs 14.4:799-832.

Goody, Jack. 1976. Production and Reproduction: A Comparative Study of the Domestic Domain . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Gronewold, Susan. 1982. "Beautiful Merchandise: Prostitution in China, 1860-1936." Women and History (Special Issue) 1:1-114.

Harrell, Stevan. 1985. "The Rich Get Children: Segmentation, Stratification, and Population in Three Chekiang Lineages, 1550-1850." In Family and Population in East Asian History , ed. Susan Hanley and Arthur Wolf. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Hartman, Heidi. 1981. "The Family as the Locus of Gender, Class, and Political Struggle: The Example of Housework." Signs 6.3:366-94.

Hershatter, Gail. 1986. The Workers of Tianjin, 1900-1949 . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Honig, Emily. 1986. Sisters and Strangers: Women in Shanghai Cotton Mills, 1919-1949 . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Jamieson, G. 1921; reprint, 1970. Chinese Family and Commercial Law . Hong Kong: Vetch & Lee.

Jaschok, Maria. 1988. Concubines and Bondservants: The Social History of a Chinese Custom . London: Zed Press.

Johnson, Elizabeth. 1976. Households and Lineages in a Chinese Urban Village . No. 77-18, 170. Ann Arbor: University Microfilms.


254

Lang, Olga. 1946. Chinese Family and Society . New Haven: Yale University Press.

Lebsock, Suzanne. 1984. The Free Women of Petersburg: Status and Culture in a Southern Town, 1784-1860 . New York: W. W. Norton.

Liu, Hui-chen Wang. 1959. The Traditional Chinese Clan Rules . Locust Valley, N.Y.: J. J. Augustin.

Liu, Tsui-jung. 1985. "The Demography of Two Chinese Clans in Hsiao-shan, Chekiang, 1650-1850." In Family and Population in East Asian History , ed. Susan Hanley and Arthur Wolf. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

McDermott, Joseph. 1981. "Bondservants in the T'ai-hu Basin during the Lace Ming: A Case of Mistaken Identities." Journal of Asian Studies 40:675-701.

McGough, James. 1976. Marriage and Adoption in Chinese Society with Special Reference to Customary Law . No. 77-5852. Ann Arbor: University Microfilms.

Meillassoux, Claude. 1983. "Female Slavery." In Women and Slavery in Africa , ed. Claire Robertson anti Martin Klein. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Meskill, Johanna. 1979. A Chinese Pioneer Family: The Lins of Wu-feng, Taiwan, 1729-1895 . Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Miers, Suzanne, and Igor Kopytoff. 1977. "African 'Slavery' as an Institution of Marginality." In Slavery in Africa: Historical and Anthropological Perspectives , ed. Suzanne Miers and Igor Kopytoff. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Nieboer, H. J. 1910; reprint, 1971. Slavery as an Industrial System: Ethnological Researches . 2d rev. ed. New York: Burt Franklin.

Pasternak, Burton. 1983. Guests of the Dragon: Social Demography of a Chinese District, 1895-1946 . New York: Columbia University Press.

Pratt, Jean. 1960. "Emigration and Unilineal Descent Groups: A Study of Marriage in a Hakka Village in the New Territories, Hong Kong." Eastern Anthropologist 13: 147-58.

Pruitt, Ida. 1979. Old Madam Yin: A Memoir of Peking Life . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Rapp, Rayna. 1978. "Family and Class in Contemporary America: Notes Towards an Understanding of Ideology." Science and Society 42:278-300.

Report. (Mui Tsai in Hong Kong and Malaya: Report of Commission ). 1937. Issued by Colonial Office, Colonial no. 125. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office.

Robertson, Claire. 1983. "Post-Proclamation Slavery in Accra: A Female Affair." In Women and Slavery in Africa , ed. Claire Robertson and Martin Klein. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Robertson, Claire, and Martin Klein. 1983. "Women's Importance in African Slave Systems." In Women and Slavery in Africa , ed. Claire Robertson and Martin Klein. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Sankar, Andrea. 1978. "Female Domestic Service in Hong Kong." In Female Servants and Economic Development , ed. Louise Tilly et al. Ann Arbor: Michigan Occasional Papers in Women's Studies, no. 1.

Shiga, Shuzo inline image 1967. Chugokukazoku hono genriinline image (Basic principles underlying Chinese family law). Tokyo: Sobunsha.

———. 1978. "Family Property anti the Law of Inheritance in Traditional China." In Chinese Family Law and Social Change in Historical and Comparative Perspective , ed. David C. Buxbaum. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Smith, Carl T. 1982. "The Chinese Church, Labour and Elites and the Mui Tsai


255

Question in the 1920's." Journal of the Hong Kong Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society 21: 91-113.

Stockard, Janice. 1989. Daughters of the Canton Delta: Marriage Patterns and Economic Strategies in South China, 1860-1930 . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Thorne, Barrie, with Marilyn Yalom, ed. 1982. Rethinking the Family: Some Feminist Questions . New York: Longman.

Topley, Marjorie. 1975. "Marriage Resistance in Kwangtung." In Women in Chinese Society , ed. Margery Wolf and Roxane Witke. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

van der Sprenkel, Sybille. 1962. Legal Institutions in Manchu China . London: Athone.

Watson, James L. 1976. "Chattel Slavery in Chinese Peasant Society: A Comparative Analysis." Ethnology 15:361-75.

———. 1980a. "Slavery as an Institution, Open and Closed Systems." In Asian and African Systems of Slavery , ed. James L. Watson. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

———. 1980b. "Transactions in People: The Chinese Market in Slaves, Servants, and Heirs." In Asian and African Systems of Slavery , ed. James L. Watson. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Watson, Rubie S. 1981. "Class Differences and Affinal Relations in South China." Man 16:593-615.

———. 1984. "Women's Property in Republican China: Rights and Practice." Republican China 10.1a:1-12.

———. 1985. Inequality among Brothers: Class and Kinship in South China . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1986. "The Named and the Nameless: Gender and Person in Chinese Society." American Ethnologist 13:619-31.

Wolf, Arthur. 1974. "Marriage and Adoption in Northern Taiwan." In Social Organization and the Applications of Anthropology: Essays in Honor of Lauriston Sharp , ed. Robert J. Smith. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Wolf, Margery. 1972. Women and the Family in Rural Taiwan . Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Wright, Marcia. 1983. "Bwanikwa: Consciousness and Protest among Slave Women in Central Africa, 1886-1911." I n Women and Slavery in Africa , ed. Claire Robertson and Martin Klein. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Yanagisako, Sylvia. 1979. "Variance in American Kinship: Implications for Cultural Analysis." American Ethnologist 5:15-29.

———. 1984. "Explicating Residence: A Cultural Analysis of Changing Households among Japanese-Americans." In Households: Comparative and Historical Studies of the Domestic Group , ed. Robert McC. Netting, Richard Wilk, and Eric Arnould. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Yang, C. K. 1959. A Chinese Village in Early Communist Transition . Cambridge: MIT Press.

Yang, Martin. 1945. A Chinese Village, Taitou, Shantung Province . New York: Columbia University Press.


256

Eight
Prostitution and the Market in Women in Early Twentieth-Century Shanghai

Gail Hershatter

In 1917 a man named Huang brought an eleven-year-old girl named Hsueh Feng to Shanghai. There he took her to the House of Pearls (Han-chu chia), an elegant brothel run by Old Three Wang, a madam who was "unsurpassed in rounding up talent for her house." Huang pawned Hsueh Feng to the brothel for 350 yuan, the pawn period being set at eight years. It is not clear whether Huang was a relative of the girl, a professional trafficker in women, or both. But apparently the girl's family knew where she was, for soon afterward some relatives appeared at the brothel and asked to see the madam. Explaining that Hsueh's parents had died and there was no money to bury them properly, the relatives asked Old Three Wang to increase the pawn price and buy Hsueh Feng outright. The madam agreed; henceforth Hsueh Feng became the permanent property of the brothel.

Eleven years passed, during which Hsueh, as a beautiful adolescent, served as a prostitute-in-training (ch'u-chi ). The details of her duties in the brothel in those years are not recorded, but she was not yet expected to have sexual relations with the customers or to entertain them alone. In 1928 she began to entertain guests, taking the professional name of Old Seven, since she was the seventh prostitute in the House of Pearls. Even then her work appears to have consisted of singing for rich men at parties; she was referred to as a "small teacher" (hsiao hsien-sheng ), a term that in the trade meant "virgin prostitute."

At one of these parties, Old Seven caught the eye of a wealthy young man named Lu Min-kang, who was a partner in an export firm with offices on the Shanghai docks. Lu, age twenty-three, was from Ch'ung-ming, north of Shanghai. Though he showed up at work only occasionally, his position in the firm was secure because his father owned substantial amounts of stock. Lu paid several formal calls on Old Seven, observing the elaborate courtesies

I wish to acknowledge helpful comments from the participants in the Conference on Marriage and Inequality in China, particularly Susan Mann, Susan Naquin, Rubie Watson, and Arthur Wolf. In addition, various drafts of this chapter were given critical readings by Wendy Brown, Christina Gilmartin, Emily Honig, Lisa Rofel, Margery Wolf, Christine Wong, and Marilyn Young. All interpretations and errors are my responsibility.


257

required of patrons in upper-class brothels. But the madam, Old Three Wang, looked on him with disfavor because she felt he did not give generous-enough tips when Old Seven sang. Protecting her investment, perhaps hoping to sell Old Seven's first night to someone who was freer with his money, the madam kept a close eye on Old Seven and refused to let her out alone.

Nevertheless, Lu found an opportunity to meet Old Seven secretly one night, and during their encounter Old Seven "broke with the behavior of a virgin prostitute." The two decided they wanted to spend their lives together, but Lu did not follow the usual procedure of offering to buy Old Seven from the madam. Instead, the couple fled the brothel one day in 1929, taking with them several suitcases of clothing and gold jewelry. The madam looked for them in vain. The next day she received a letter from a lawyer. The letter said that Old Seven had been pawned as a prostitute, but that her pawn period had long ago expired. She had been young, ignorant, and trampled underfoot, the letter continued, and now that she was grown she wanted to regain her freedom and break relations with the brothel. The lawyer gave Old Three Wang two days to produce the "illegal" contract that bound Old Seven to the brothel so that it could be invalidated. If she did not meet the deadline, the letter warned, she would be dealt with according to law.

Undaunted, Old Three Wang retained a lawyer of her own. She also located Lu and Old Seven in their hiding place in the southern part of the city and sent someone there to talk to (and perhaps threaten) them. When he saw the visitor, Lu "raged and roared," and the encounter concluded on worse terms than it had begun. Shortly thereafter the courts undertook an investigation of the case (SP July 10, 1929:7).

The legal disposition of this case was not reported in the press, and it is not clear what became of Old Seven. But her story contains many elements common to the lives of prostitutes in Republican-era Shanghai: the poverty and crisis in Hsueh Feng's family, the pawning or sale of daughters into prostitution, the long training period and close guarding of prostitutes in the more exclusive brothels, and the elaborate rituals of entertainment and negotiation that preceded any sexual encounter with an upper-class prostitute. In finding a young patron who was willing to free her from the life, Hsueh was fulfilling the dream of many young women who hoped to leave the brothels on the arm of a rich man. The resort to litigation was characteristic of both madams and prostitutes. And the use of violence and intimidation, though only hinted at in this particular case, was an integral part of work relations in the trade.

Recent scholars and activists writing on prostitution have renamed it "sex work" (Delacoste and Alexander 1987), reminding us that it must be understood in the context of other forms of paid labor available to women. In Shanghai prostitution was indeed one of just a few situations in which women could earn an income. But the Shanghai market in female labor was


258

not a free one, in two senses. First, women had little choice about where they worked because the female labor market was structured by regional and family connections. Second, women themselves often were not free workers; that is, they were frequently kidnapped or purchased by contractors who then sold their labor to factories or sold them outright as maids, concubines, and prostitutes. An even more common arrangement for prostitutes was to be pawned to a brothel by their families or by traffickers for a specified period of time. Whether sold or pawned, a woman had limited or no control over her income and working conditions, nor did she have the right to leave a brothel unless she redeemed the pawn pledge. In placing Shanghai prostitution on the continuum of work, we must be mindful that the women themselves were treated primarily as commodities rather than producers of commodities.

Prostitution must be placed on another continuum as well: one of claims on women's sexual services. This continuum included concubinage and marriage as well as prostitution because all of these were means by which others acquired claims on a woman's person.[1] All women in late imperial and Republican China, Sue Gronewold writes in her study of prostitution, were "regarded fundamentally as disposable merchandise, as commodities. The prostitute's singularity lay in being a strictly sexual commodity" (1982:50). Prostitution and marriage thus become merely different forms of transaction in the same market. Although this formulation calls attention to an important similarity between married women and prostitutes, it diverts attention from the struggle that prostitutes in particular waged, sometimes successfully, to gain a modicum of control over the disposition of their sexual services.

In China, decisions about entry into marriage or prostitution were usually made for the woman by others, most frequently family members. Among the poor, prostitution and marriage drew from the same pool of women; families who could afford to do so were at great pains to keep their daughters eligible for marriage and off the prostitution market. Sometimes poor married women found it necessary to work as prostitutes; sometimes prostitutes left the brothels to become concubines or wives. Both prostitution and marriage exhibited an elaborate hierarchy of different statuses and degrees of permanence; arrangements in both varied by class. Both were vehicles for mobility up and down. Prostitution even mimicked certain of the rituals of marriage and family life.

Yet prostitution and marriage exhibited important differences as well. A prostitute was dependent upon her madam, who controlled her contact with both her natal family and her customers. (Pimps played a less important role, helping some brothels to solicit customers but apparently having little direct control over the prostitutes.) The madam had long-term claims on the body of the prostitute, while the claims of the client were short term. After a pawned prostitute served out her allotted time, her natal or marital family


259

might reassert their claims on her. In short, demands on a prostitute's person were divided among a number of parties, whereas in marriage short- and long-term claims were not separated in this way. Prostitution, unlike marriage, was not for the purpose of reproduction, although both married women and prostitutes attempted to use pregnancy as a strategy to enhance their own positions. Prostitution was regarded as a temporary stage in a society in which all women were expected to marry. This chapter examines similarities between prostitution and marriage in Shanghai, as well as movements of individual women from one institution to the other.

The changing Shanghai market in women must be understood in the context of the city's rapid growth in the first half of the twentieth century.[2] The population of Shanghai, including the International Settlement and the French Concession, almost tripled between 1910 and 1930 from about a million to more than three million. At the conclusion of World War II its population was roughly the same as in 1930, but by 1947 it had grown again by one-third.[3] Immigrants from other parts of China made up more than 82 percent of this population in 1910, more than 90 percent in 1930 (Lo Chih-ju 1932:27, table 43). Women migrants to Shanghai found work in manufacturing, particularly cotton textiles; as household servants or wet nurses; as itinerant peddlers; and as entertainers or prostitutes.[4]

But far more men than women immigrated to Shanghai. In the Chinese-governed sector of the city in the early 1930s, there were typically 135 men to every 100 women, dropping to an average of 124 to 100 in the three years after World War II (SCA 1933, Population, 2, table 3; SSWH 1948: 14, 16, 18). The ratio was even more skewed among Chinese adults in the International Settlement (156:100 in 1930) and the French Concession (164:100 in 1930) (Lo Chih-ju 1932:30). Republican period social reformers were fond of pointing out that the predominance of unattached men in the urban population increased the demand for commercial sexual services.

To reconstruct the living and working conditions of prostitutes in early twentieth-century Shanghai, this paper begins with a description of the complex class structure of prostitution and a rough estimate of the numbers of women involved. Then it explores common elements in the family background and personal history of prostitutes in addition to the financial arrangements by which a woman entered a brothel. It examines the brothel as a social world with its own rules, codes, and risks and also asks how a prostitute's working life mimicked the rituals of courtship and marriage (with respect to customers) and family life (with respect to madams). Finally, the essay considers the "career path" of prostitutes, particularly the exit into marriage or concubinage. How permeable was the boundary around prostitution, by whom could it be crossed, and under what circumstances? The paper concludes with some observations about the Shanghai market in women.


260

Hierarchies of Prostitution

One way to untangle the complex structure of prostitution in Shanghai is to look at the types of prostitutes that provided sexual services to different classes of men, from the well-educated scion of the elite to the transient foreign sailor. At the beginning of the twentieth century, the prostitutes most often written about were those who entertained the local literati. Famed as singers and storytellers, they were commonly addressed with the respectful term hsien-sheng , most frequently translated into English as "sing-song girl." The public spaces where they performed were known as storytelling houses, their private dwellings as storytellers' residences (shu-yu ). The term shu-yu was also used to refer to them as a group ("Demi-monde" 1923:783; T'u 1948:hsia , 76; Lemière 1923:127-28; Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 1-2).

Storytelling-house prostitutes traced their entertainer pedigree back a thousand years. Famed for their beauty, their extravagant dress, and their elaborate opium and tobacco pipes, they were equally renowned for their ability to sing and accompany themselves on stringed instruments, skill at composing poetry, refined artistic sensibilities, and conversational skill. Their professional names (chosen upon their entry into the house) were meant to invoke both sensual pleasure and literary associations. Some took studio names (chai ) such as "Fragrant Nest" or "Drunken Flowers Retreat." Others chose names like those used by the male literati, such as "the master of the lodge wherein verses are hummed." One famous nineteenth-century sing-song girl took the name Lin Tai-yü, after the heroine of Dream of the Red Chamber (Lemière 1923:127-28, 130; Arlington 1923:317; "Demi-monde" 1923:783).

Members of the storytelling-house class regarded themselves as skilled entertainers rather than providers of sexual services; they prided themselves on "selling their voices rather than their bodies." One Republican-era description of them, colored perhaps by nostalgia, reported that these women had such high moral principles that if one was discovered having secret relations with a sweetheart, then her bedding was burned and she was driven out. Other accounts say they did "sell their beauty" in their residences, but kept this practice secret and made their reputations as singers (Lemière 1923:127-28; Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 1-2; Liu 1936:136; "Demi-monde" 1923:783; T'u 1948:hsia , 76). In the early decades of the twentieth century the popularity of this geisha-style service declined; at least one source hints that the cause of its downfall was the unwillingness of the women to have sexual relations with their customers. By the 1920s the storytelling-house class had been absorbed into the next lower class of prostitutes, though the term shu-yu was used intermittently as late as 1948 ("Demi-monde" 1923:783; Lemière 1923:127-28; T'u 1948:hsia , 76; Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 1-2; Yü 1948:11).


261

The next lower class, called "long three" (ch'ang-san ), was named after a domino with two groups of three dots each. Traditionally, "long-three" prostitutes charged three yuan for drinking with guests and three more for spending the night with them; the name remained long after the fee structure changed. Like the storytelling-house women, the "long-three" prostitutes performed classical songs and scenes from opera, dressed in elaborate costumes, and specialized in hosting banquets and gambling parties for merchants and well-placed officials. In the era before taxis became common, women rode to these parties in horse-drawn carriages or were carried on the shoulders of male brothel servants "like a Buddhist pagoda," providing live advertisement for the services of their house (T'u 1948:hsia , 76). The "long-three" brothels in Hui-le Li, a lane off Fu-chou Road, were the most famous. Sometimes wealthy customers would request that a woman accompany them to a dramatic performance or other place of entertainment (Henderson 1871:14; T'u 1948:hsia , 76). The woman's brothel charged a set fee for all such services. Though they were less sexually available than lower-class prostitutes, a patron who went through a long "courtship" process and paid elaborate fees to the woman and her madam could hope for sexual favors ("Demi-monde" 1923:783-85; T'u 1948:hsia , 76; Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 1-2; Yü 1948:11; Liu 1936:136; Yi 1933:39).

Next in the hierarchy were the "one-two" prostitutes, also named for dominos. In the 1940s their fees were quoted as one yuan for providing melon seeds and fruit (called a "dry and wet basin") and two yuan for drinking companionship, though an evening in their company could cost considerably more. Sources agree that the singing of "one-two" prostitutes was not as good, nor their sexual services as expensive, as the "long three." "One-two" houses were most numerous along Peking Road and in the French Concession (Yü 1948:11; T'u 1948:hsia , 76-77; "Demi-monde" 1923:785; Wiley 1929:65; Yi 1933:39).

The largest group of brothels in the next grade down were called "salt-pork shops" (hsien-rou chuang ). Unlike all the grades above them, they were devoted exclusively to the on-demand satisfaction of male copulative desires, with little attention to singing, banqueting, or other ancillary forms of entertainment. Women were the "salt pork"; as a 1932 guidebook put it, "the price in the shop depends on the taste of the meat. Everyone knows that a slice costs three yuan, and an entire night five to eight yuan." In these houses customers were said to divide up the women as though cutting salt pork (Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 27-28). Another 1930s guide reminded its readers that salt pork was no longer fresh meat and that it might in fact be rotten (Wang Chung-hsien 1935:23-24). In the late 1940s laborers were the main clientele of the salt-pork shops. Many of these brothels were located near the French Concession's Bridge of the Eight Immortals (Pa-hsien ch'iao ) (T'u 1948:hsia , 77; Wang 1932:"P'iao," 25; Yü 1948:11).


262

By far the largest group of prostitutes in Republican Shanghai were the "pheasants" (yeh-chi or chih-chi ), streetwalkers whose name suggests both their gaudy dress and their habit of "go[ing] about from place to place like wild birds" ("Demi-monde" 1923:785-86). Every evening groups of them could be seen on both sides of the main streets aggressively seeking customers. Guidebooks of the period repeatedly warned Shanghai visitors to beware of the pheasants, whose eager assaults on passersby could shade over into pickpocketing. Mixing his ornithological metaphors, one author warned that pheasants fastened onto their prey "like an eagle seizing a chick" (T'ang 1931:152-53). Their prices as reported in 1932 ranged from one yuan for what was euphemistically called "one cannon blast-ism" (yi-p'ao chu-yi ) to seven yuan for a night (Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 49).

Although pheasants worked the streets, they were by no means independent of the brothel system. Most operated under the control of madams, often under more restrictive conditions than their higher-status sisters. Brothel attendants supervised them as they went about finding customers, who were then brought back to the brothel (T'u 1948:hsia , 77). "No matter the weather, hot or cold, rain, frost, or snow, when evening came they must stand in groups and call out to men and on the least response they must take hold of them and cajole them to respond," commented a 1923 article. "If not successful, the girls were beaten" ("Demi-monde" 1923:786). In at least one respect they were certainly worse off than other prostitutes: because they did not remain in brothels, they frequently came into conflict with the local police, who enforced the municipal ordinance against street soliciting (see, for example, SP July 22, 1929:7). One guide advised Shanghai visitors that the only way to shake off a determined pheasant was to drag her into the street, because then she would become fearful of police intervention and desist in her efforts (T'ang 1931:152-53).

Lowest of all in the hierarchy of prostitution were the employees of brothels called "flower-smoke rooms" (hua-yen chien ) and "nailsheds" (ting-p'eng ). Flower-smoke rooms were places where a customer could smoke opium and visit prostitutes ("flowers") simultaneously. After 1933, when opium was banned, they reportedly disappeared. Nailsheds, scattered throughout the city, were rudimentary brothels that catered to rickshaw pullers and other laborers; the prices ranged from two chiao for quick sex to one yuan for the night (1932 figures) (T'ang 1931:154; Yi 1933:39; T'u 1948:hsia , 77; Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 50-51).

Like workers in other sectors of the Shanghai economy, most prostitutes were not of local origin. Outsiders were in the majority in part because Republican-period Shanghai was an expanding city that attracted peasants with the hope of work while rural crisis and war were pushing them out of the countryside. They also reflected the presence in Shanghai of powerful merchant and official cliques who hailed from Canton, Ningpo, and the cities of


263

the lower Yangtze; men from all these regions apparently preferred prostitutes from their own native places. Finally, those who trafficked in sexual services preferred to resell women far enough from home that their families would not clamor for the return of the goods or a share of the profits (Wiley 1929:52-53). Brothel owners who bought women from other regions increased their ability to control them because "if the prostitute [was] removed from her home community she [was] absolutely at the mercy of her keepers" (ibid., 66-67). For the same reason, "Shanghai girls, as a rule, when sold or mortgaged, are shipped off to some far away place," as one contemporary account noted (Lemière 1923:133).

As with most occupations in Shanghai, regionalism played an important role in the hierarchy of prostitution. Women in the top two classes came mainly from cities in the Kiangnan, notably Suchou (famed for its beauties), Wuhsi, Nanking, Hangchou, and Ch'angchou (Lemière 1923:133; Yi 1933: 39-40; Wiley 1929:53, citing Morris 1916). Even those in the top classes who came from Shanghai proper did their best to affect a Suchou accent and claim Suchou as their native place (T'u 1948:hsia , 76-77; Yü 1948:11). Prostitutes of the grade of "one-two" and below came largely from Yangchou and other parts of Supei, like the laborers who patronized their brothels. Supei prostitutes also carved out special niches for themselves in the sexual service market; for example, some specialized in rowing out to the junks moored on the Huang-p'u River to sell themselves to the Chinese sailors (Yi 1933:39-40; SP , April 6, 1929:7). This intersection of class and regional divisions, with Supei people at the bottom, mirrored the larger occupational structure of Shanghai (Honig 1987).

Regional divisions shaped prostitution in other ways as well. Distinct groups of prostitutes from Canton and Ningpo serviced the merchant and official groups from those cities who were resident in Shanghai. In the 1920s warlord conflicts drove many wealthy Cantonese to migrate to Shanghai, where they opened large businesses like Sincere and Wing On; the ranks of Cantonese long-three prostitutes increased accordingly. Ningpo prostitutes, supervised by madams, lived in and worked out of hotels in the Wu Ma Lu and Da Hsin Chieh area, receiving guests with Ningpo-style snacks of salted fish and crabs. The high-status Cantonese and Ningpo prostitutes kept to their own communities and generally did not welcome guests who were not from their native places (Wiley 1929:52; Yi 1933:39-40; Lemière 1923:133; Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 34-35).

Another group of Cantonese women, who traced their presence in Shanghai to the early nineteenth century, specialized in entertaining foreign sailors. They were known as "saltwater sisters" (hsien-shui mei ), which may have been a reference to their maritime patrons; but one source explains that their name was a transliteration of "handsome maid" into Cantonese (hansui mui ) (T'u 1948:hsia , 77). They were reputed to be "more hygienic than some


264

others, partly because of the Cantonese love of cleanliness, and partly because they wish to attract foreigners" ("Demi-monde" 1923:787-88). (This emphasis on cleanliness was far more pronounced in guides to Shanghai written by foreigners than in the Chinese literature, though the latter also featured occasional warnings about venereal disease.) Nevertheless, their solicitation of foreign sailors, and the resultant spread of venereal disease, attracted the attention of the British admiral who in 1877 requested that Shanghai open a lock hospital (a hospital devoted to the treatment of venereal disease) to examine and register Cantonese prostitutes. Undaunted, the women proceeded to use their hospital registration cards, each with a photo identification, as advertisements for their services. Examinations continued until 1920, when prostitution was officially (though ineffectively) phased out in the International Settlement (SVC 1920:83-84).

Foreign prostitutes came to Shanghai from all over the world, recruited by the shadowy traffickers that reformers called "white slavers." Among them were many Russians, whose numbers grew larger after the Russian Revolution; in the 1930s one observer noted that eight thousand Russian prostitutes resided in Shanghai. Many were brought in from the northern city of Harbin and either worked openly as prostitutes in "Russian houses" (Lo-sung t'ang-tzu ) in the French Concession and the Hung-k'ou area or became taxi dancers who sold sexual services for an extra fee. Japanese prostitutes also worked in the Hung-k'ou area, sometimes doubling as maidservants or waitresses. Foreign prostitutes apparently drew most of their clientele from among the foreign community and transient sailors, but some of them entertained Chinese customers as well (O'Callaghan 1968:11-12; Champly 1934:188; Hauser 1940:267; T'ang 1931:153-54; T'u 1948:hsia , 77; Yi 1933:41).[5]

In addition to native place, beauty also determined a woman's place in the hierarchy of prostitution. A Suchou woman, no matter how well her relatives or fellow villagers were known to the owner of a long-three brothel, could not hope to become a prostitute there unless she was beautiful. Less attractive women could work only as servants in these houses. At the same time, particularly beautiful women from other regions sometimes entered high-class houses without the benefit of connections. One small but prosperous brothel, a former resident of the neighborhood recounted, had two prostitutes, one from Suchou and one from Shantung, but "the second one was so beautiful you couldn't tell she was from Shantung." As one moved down the hierarchy, the prostitutes reportedly became less beautiful (Sun et al. 1986).

A third factor determining a woman's place in the hierarchy was age. Many prostitutes in ch'ang-san houses first entered the brothels as children, purchased by the madams as "foster daughters" (yang-nü ). If a woman had already passed adolescence, then no upper-class house would want her;


265

madams reasoned that she was already untrainable or that she would not be able to work enough years to pay back the investment. Pheasants and other low-class prostitutes were frequently in their twenties or even older (Yü 1948:11; Wiley 1929:66-67). Of five hundred prostitutes surveyed in 1948, almost half had begun work between the ages of fifteen and nineteen; the largest group was between the ages of twenty and twenty-four at the time of the interviews (Yü 1948:11). Women who began work at the top of the hierarchy might descend to less prestigious establishments as they aged if they were unable to devise a successful exit strategy.

Numbers

It is impossible to say how many women worked as prostitutes in Shanghai. The inconsistent attitude of multiple municipal governments meant that no systematic statistics were collected. Even more unlucky for the researcher, brothel owners often had an interest in concealing their business from the authorities, if only to avoid paying bribes. Virtually every observer of the Shanghai scene commented that licensed brothels were outnumbered by unlicensed ones and by disguised forms of prostitution. Taxi dancers in the dance halls, masseuses in the massage parlors, waitresses in the vaudeville houses, guides in the tourist agencies, female vendors of newspapers, cigarettes, and fruit, and itinerant menders of sailors' clothing all engaged in prostitution, either because their jobs required it or because their precarious incomes needed augmenting (T'ang 1931:154; Yü 1948:11). Though they were seldom counted among the ranks of prostitutes in contemporary surveys, these part-time, or "disguised," prostitutes must be considered in estimating the size of the sexual-service sector and understanding the employment alternatives for women.

The fragmentary statistics available indicate the steady growth of prostitution. A 1920 report of the Special Vice Commission (SVC) counted 4,522 Chinese prostitutes in the International Settlement alone, or 1 out of every 147 Chinese residents, male and female, of the settlement. If the greater population of Shanghai was taken as 1.5 million, the report added, and if prostitutes in the French Concession were figured in, then 1 in 300 Chinese residents of Shanghai sold sexual services for a living (SVC 1920:84). These figures did not include what the report referred to as "sly" prostitutes, and in fact another set of statistics collected at around the same time found more than 60,000 prostitutes at work in the two foreign areas, most of them of pheasant rank or below (Wiley 1929:45; Yi 1933:39). By 1935 combined estimates of licensed and unlicensed prostitutes ran to 100,000, with much of the increase attributed to rural disaster and Depression-related factory closings (Lo Ch'iung 1935:37). A postwar study put the number of full-time prostitutes at 50,000 but suggested that the figure should be doubled to take


266

account of women "whose activities approach those of prostitutes" (Yü 1948:10). If the Shanghai population at that time is taken as 4.2 million, then 1 in every 42 city residents was directly involved in prostitution. There may even have been more prostitutes than cotton spinners. Shanghai, China's largest industrial city, had about 84,000 cotton spinners out of a total of 173,432 women working in industry (Honig 1986:24-25).[6] But prostitution played a part in the Shanghai economy far beyond its direct significance as an employer of women. Many a small shop survived on the sale of goods and services to the upper-class brothels. "In the vicinity of her residence," a writer observed in 1929, "are numerous tailoring shops, hair dressers, makers of silk and satin shoes, embroidery shops, whose trade is enriched by her patronage" (Wiley 1929:74). Brothels also provided a venue for the meeting of the Shanghai powerful; merchants concluded deals and officials made alliances in upper-class brothels (T'u 1948:hsia , 76). For all of these reasons, prostitution touched virtually every sphere of Shanghai life.

Entry

Poverty led most women into prostitution, poverty that either drove their families to sell them, caused them to choose prostitution themselves, or made them vulnerable to the wiles of traffickers. Of twenty news stories about prostitutes reported in the Shanghai newspaper Shih-pao between March and November 1929, half explicitly mentioned family poverty as the cause of entry into prostitution. Five of the stories mentioned that the women were fatherless (three were orphans). Eight women had been sold or pawned by relatives (including parents, spouses, and others) and ten by traffickers; one had agreed to enter prostitution herself to pay off family debts. In the remaining case, two women were approached by traffickers but escaped (SP March 2; April 6, 8, 12, 19; May 23, 29; June 10, 17; July 6, 10, 15, 18, 19; August 21; September 20; October 14, 20; November 16, 25, 1929:7).[7]

Little is known about how poor families decided whether to sell their daughters as brides, maidservants, or prostitutes, though it is generally assumed that they attempted to emulate richer families in keeping their daughters on the marriage market and out of the brothels. But for a poor woman marriage was not a lifetime guarantee of respectability.[8] In the twenty cases just mentioned, eight of the prostitutes were married; most of them had been kidnapped, but one had been pawned by her husband, and another was tricked into prostitution when she left her husband to look for work because he refused to support her. Of the five hundred prostitutes surveyed in 1948, two-thirds were unmarried, a fifth were widows, and more than 9 percent had living spouses (Yü 1948:11; Yü and Wong 1949:236, table V). The percentage of married women and widows was higher among lower-class prostitutes (SP August 26, 1929:7; Yü and Wong 1949:236, table V). Though the data are not conclusive, they suggest that disintegration of fami-


267

ly networks through death or poverty, or detachment from family networks in order to find work in Shanghai, greatly increased a woman's chances of ending up in a brothel.

Women entered brothels of all classes in Shanghai under one of three arrangements. A small number (estimated by one investigator at less than 5 percent) entered as employees, or "free persons" (tzu-chi shen-t'i or tzu-chia shen-t'i ), paid all expenses themselves, and controlled their own work. A free prostitute in theory controlled her own earnings, but in practice she had to give half or more of her income to the madam in return for use of the brothel facilities. Often the madam kept complete control of the finances and paid each prostitute a fixed salary per season ("Demi-monde" 1923:784-85; Lemière 1923:131; Yi 1933:40-41; Lo Ch'iung 1935:35).

The majority of prostitutes were mortgaged (ya-chang or pao-chang ) by relatives, traffickers, or themselves for a fixed term, much like pawned goods ("Demi-monde" 1923:784-85; Lemière 1923:131; Yi 1933:40-41). In six cases of pawning reported in the Shanghai press in 1929, the price ranged from seventy to four hundred yuan.[9] Women in the upper price range were virgins who could be expected to command a high defloration fee (SP April 8, 19; May 29; July 10; August 21; October 20, 1929:7).

The remaining women, known as "completely uprooted" (tu-chueh , or t'ao-jen ), were sold outright to the brothel by relatives or traffickers ("Demi-monde" 1923:784-85; Lemière 1923:131; Yi 1933:40-41; Zhang and Sang 1987:32-33). Prostitutes who had been sold, rather than pawned, were regarded by the madams as their private property. They could be released from service only if someone paid what the brothel owner regarded as "a fair market price" (O'Callaghan 1968:13-14). In seven cases reported in the press where women were sold outright, the price ranged from 140 to 600 yuan (SP April 6; June 10; July 15; October 14; November 16, 25, 1929:7).

Trafficking in women was big business in Shanghai. Traffickers, both men and women, would go to rural districts that suffered from flood or famine and purchase girls and young women "for a couple of dollars apiece," reported a foreign observer in 1940, "and if they were lucky, they could resell the choice ones for a thousand dollars in Shanghai" (Hauser 1940:268). Equally common, and featured more prominently in the cautionary tales of the Shanghai press, were urban traffickers who preyed upon recent migrants to the city and sold them into brothels by trickery or force. "The methods of the procurers and procuresses are so subtle and ingenious that no one—unless associated with the traffic—knows exactly how they do their work," warned one foreign writer in 1927:

Their favorite recruiting grounds are the theaters, tea houses, amusement parks, and other public places. . . . Many of the hotel boys, the theater ushers, the waiters in the restaurants, the flower girls, newspaper sellers, Mafoos (carriage men), maid servants, and even ricksha coolies are aiding and abetting in this tragic. The most dangerous of all perhaps are the women hair dressers, and


268

the sellers of jewelry, because they have easy access to the household and can exercise their influence freely. (McCartney 1927, cited in Wiley 1929:56)

Some professional traffickers pretended to be labor recruiters, promising to introduce women into legitimate jobs as servants or factory workers in Shanghai (SP March 2, 1929:7; Zhang and Sang 1987:31). They played on native-place ties to win the confidence of the women and their families. A woman from Suchou named Yang A-p'o, for instance, became acquainted with a man named Feng San-chuan who also resided in Shanghai. When Feng had to go to Hangchou on business, Yang offered to find his wife a maidservant's job so that she could remain in Shanghai. Several months later Feng returned from Hangchou looking for his wife, only to find that Yang had sold her into a brothel. Yang offered him two hundred yuan to acquire another wife, but he declined and sued her in court (SP April 12, 1929:7).

Other traffickers made no attempt to entice women, but instead kidnapped them by force. One such case involved a married woman named Hsiao (née Wang) who was grabbed by three men as she washed clothes on a riverbank in Supei. Gagged and restrained, she was taken to Shanghai. Her case came to public attention when, after several months of streetwalking, she spotted her kidnapper on the street and alerted the police (SP April 6, 1929:7). Another woman, new to the city, was forcibly pawned by the owner of the rickshaw her husband pulled (SP August 21, 1929:7). A third sought lodging in a local monastery while looking for work in the city, only to be mortgaged into prostitution by the monks (SP October 20, 1929:7). It was not uncommon for male traffickers to rape or seduce young women before selling them into prostitution, thus making their return to a spouse or the marriage market more difficult (T'ang 1931:481; SP October 14; November 25, 1929:7). A woman's entry into prostitution thus was sometimes accomplished by outright violence that removed her from whatever protection her family could offer.

Brothel Life

In Ta-ch'ing li, a lane off of Chiu-chiang Road, residents of every class crowded together in the 1940s. Doctors, fortune-tellers, owners of opium and gambling dens, businessmen and shop employees lived in close proximity. The monied classes resided in large apartments, while their poorer neighbors lived ten to a room. Of the four hundred residences in the lane, twenty-four were brothels. Though not of the highest grade, they nevertheless boasted many of the accoutrements of fancy establishments. In the late 1940s Ta-ch'ing li was home to 101 prostitutes, many recruited by the madams from their own native places.

To open a brothel in this lane or anywhere else in Shanghai, a madam


269

(known as the lao-pao ) needed not only. money but also "background": marriage or a liaison with a local hoodlum, connections to the neighborhood police or to gang bosses. Local madam Ting Ts'ai-ch'un, for instance, was the lover of a police officer. Sometimes the madam's money and "background" had been acquired in a previous career as a prostitute. In other cases madams had begun their careers as brothel servants; this was the case with Big Pockmark and Small Pockmark, two madams in Ta-ch'ing li (Sun et al. 1986). Madams frequently owned as well as operated these establishments (Henderson 1871:12), though sometimes they shared ownership with a male boss. If a madam owned the establishment, she took charge of renting the house, meeting police regulations, and recruiting women (Wiley 1929: 59). After they opened their brothels, madams had to cultivate connections with the local police, usually through the payment of quasi-legal taxes like the "street-standing tax" (chan-chieh chuan ) and the "friendliness tax" (ho-ch'i chuan ). Prompt payment of these fees ensured that when the police came to inspect an establishment there would be no trouble, and if a madam became embroiled in a court case the local police would intercede. These police connections could be invoked by the madam in conflicts with the neighbors or used to bring an unruly prostitute into line (Lu 1938:14-15).

Once a woman was sold or pawned to a brothel, the madam had claims on her person that resembled those shopowners had on their apprentices or labor bosses on their contracted laborers. In the upper-class brothels, at least, the harshness of the madam/prostitute relationship was obscured by the language of kinship. Most prostitutes in Ta-ch'ing li, for instance, were addressed by terms used for adopted daughters and were taught to address the madams as "mama." The "family" consisted of a "father" (the owner or the madam's paramour), a "mother" (the madam), five or six adopted "daughters," and servants to do the housework. Larger brothels had a complete complement of cooks, bookkeepers, runners, and rickshaw pullers, but the Ta-ch'ing li establishments were more modest. The madams played cards or gambled with the neighbors, who were careful to avoid epithets like "madam" or "prostitute" when a conflict broke out because such an insult could not be easily repaired. In general, the madams treated these young women well, gave them enough to eat and wear, and made sure that they were strictly supervised by female servants. The more beautiful prostitutes-in-training were educated in chess, poetry, and music. During the day the "daughters" of the madams dressed like any other girl on the lane. Only their habit of sleeping until noon and their resplendent dress after five in the evening distinguished them from the neighbors (Sun et al. 1986; "Demi-monde" 1923:785).

Relationships in the brothels mimicked familial relationships in less. benign ways as well. Daughters in most Chinese families had little to say about the choice of their marriage partner or the timing of the match. At marriage,


270

they passed from the control of their natal families to that of their husbands, who had claims on their labor and their sexual and reproductive services. Similarly, prostitutes exercised no autonomy over when and to whom they would begin to sell their sexual services. A "daughter" in one of these houses was carefully groomed for her first night with a customer, which usually happened sometime after she turned fourteen. The privilege of defloration (k'ai-pao ) was expensive, and the madam would do her best to locate a wealthy businessman or industrialist whose first-night fee would repay the cost of raising the girl. The man who could afford such a fee was permitted to take the young woman to a rented room for the night; the entire defloration fee went to the madam. In top-class houses, first-night rituals were especially elaborate. The occasion was marked by a solemn ceremony that included lighting candles and bowing to images, much like a marriage rite. The patron then hosted a banquet for his friends at the brothel, a procedure known as "celebrating the flower" (tso hua-t'ou ) (Sun et al. 1986).

Little is known about how young women were prepared for their first sexual encounter. In some respects they appear to have been as sequestered, and as ignorant, as their counterparts who were married to upper-class men. Madams in the higher-grade brothels took care that their virgin "daughters" did not go out unchaperoned; they worried about the girls, recalled a resident of one brothel district, "just like parents worried about their children." They did not want to risk a casual sexual encounter with a local hoodlum, or a love affair, and the consequent loss of the lucrative first-night fee.

Even after a prostitute had spent her first night with a man, the madam continued to exercise a great deal of control over the sale of her services (what kind, when, how often, to whom, and for how much money). As mentioned earlier, providing sexual services was a minor part of an upper-class prostitute's duties. She spent much of her time attending parties given by powerful men, where she engaged in light conversation, drinking, and music making (Wei 1930:13). In the 1920s she was paid one yuan for each call, even if it was only several minutes in duration, and might make dozens of such stops in the course of a working evening, either alone or accompanied by a servant (Lemière 1923:131; Wiley 1929:72). Sometimes wealthy customers would request that a prostitute accompany them to a dramatic performance or other place of entertainment (Henderson 1871:14; T'u 1948:hsia , 76). The woman's brothel charged a set fee for all such services.

An upper-class prostitute thus moved around more than the sheltered daughters of respectable urban families. As one contemporary observer put it, "She can visit the races, the theatre, make journeys unaccompanied by a male member of the family, and engage in many other activities denied to her sisters within the home" (Wiley 1929:74). It is not clear, however, that an upper-class prostitute was able to control where she went, when, or with


271

whom; much of her social schedule was probably arranged by the madam. The ability to move around did not necessarily mean freedom of movement.

But there were exceptions to the ironclad control of the madams. Very famous or very beautiful prostitutes had some control over their own sexual services. And money was not the only variable; as one guidebook lamented, "Many are those who spend ten thousand pieces of gold, and never get to touch her" (T'u 1948:hsia , 76). A 1932 guide to Shanghai, in a section entitled "Key to Whoring" ("P'iao ti men-ching"), elaborated on this theme. It explained that some patrons could not "get into the water" even after hosting several expensive banquets, while others "tasted the flavor" without hosting even one. The key, explained the author, lay in the behavior of the patron. He should be careful to exhibit not only wealth but also good taste in dress and choice of male companions. If he was "foolish when appropriate and serious when appropriate," then even the most popular prostitute would eventually become a "prisoner of war at [his] feet" (Wang Ting-chiu 1932:"P'iao," 6). Accounts of this kind never mentioned the madam as arbiter of such encounters; the woman was portrayed as having a degree of autonomy in her choice of customers.

Although upper-class prostitutes often commanded high fees, they had little or no direct control over the income they earned. Direct fees for a woman's services were usually paid to the brothel staff, not to the prostitute. The more elegant brothels "had their shroffs and they sent their customers chits at the end of the month, like any other business establishment" (Hauser 1940:268). A house made money not only on its women but also on its banquet facilities and domino games; the madams, rather than the prostitutes, received this income (Wiley 1929:60). When a high-class prostitute went out on a social call, accompanied by her attendants, she was expected to divide the money she received with servants, musicians, and the brothel owner (Lemière 1923:131).

Three-quarters of the five hundred prostitutes questioned in 1948 said their income was average or above (chung-teng yi-shang ), though their comparison group was not specified; the investigators commented that since the currency devaluation prostitutes were much better off than salaried urban workers. But the survey added that "after exploitation by the brothel owners and middlemen, and after waste and consumption, their life is by no means well-to-do" (Yü 1948:13). One of the few ways that an upper-class prostitute could amass wealth of her own was if a customer gave her money or presents in addition to paying the madam's fee. This private wealth was known as ssu-fang ch'ien , the same term used for a married woman's private savings (Sun et al. 1986; R. Watson 1984:4-9). But a woman did not always have clear title to these presents. In a 1929 case, for instance, a popular prostitute received some valuable jewelry from an admirer. Later she fell ill and pawned


272

the jewelry to pay her medical bills. When one of the Shanghai tabloids published this information, her erstwhile patron was furious and demanded that she return the jewelry. Unable to comply, she tried to kill herself by jumping from a ferry sampan into the river (SP May 20, 1929:7).

As one moved down the hierarchy of prostitution, women apparently had even less control over the sale of their sexual services. in the "one-two" houses, customers were accepted readily whether they were regulars or strangers (T'u 1948:hsia , 77). Prostitutes in the salt-pork shops and even lower-grade establishments received customers in cubicles called "pigeon sheds" (ko-tzu p'eng ), each one just big enough for a bed. The women spent a certain amount of time with each customer, depending on the size of the fee, then went on to the next one (Sun et al. 1986; Zhang and Sang 1987:32). The pheasants, too, remained under surveillance by brothel servants, even when soliciting on the streets. Neither their freedom from the physical confines of the brothel nor the fact that as a group they were somewhat older than upper-class prostitutes guaranteed them greater control over their working lives. In addition, women who had been sold outright to a brothel apparently had less freedom to refuse customers than "free prostitutes" (Zhang and Sang 1987:33).

In the 1948 survey of five hundred prostitutes, most women were found to have had ten to thirty sexual encounters per month, with some women reporting as many as sixty (Yü 1948:13). But even the high figure may not accurately reflect the experience of lower-class prostitutes. Madams reportedly forced these women to have sexual relations with anywhere from four to twenty men a night, while saltwater sisters sometimes serviced twenty to thirty customers a night (Lo Ch'iung 1935:36; Zhang and Sang 1987:32; T'ang 1931:153). Such accounts are indirectly supported by the complaint of reformers that lower-class prostitutes were the chief cause of venereal disease because they spread it more widely and quickly than others (Yü 1948:13; "Demi-monde" 1923:786).

In some brothels women were expected to continue work even if they were menstruating or in the second trimester of pregnancy; such practices are said to have led to disorders ranging from menorrhagia to frequent miscarriage. After a miscarriage, a prostitute was put back to work as quickly as possible (Zhang and Sang 1987:32; Lo Ch'iung 1935:36). To prevent pregnancy, madams gave their prostitutes live tadpoles to eat on the theory that the "cold element" in tadpoles would counteract the "heat" of pregnancy. The same remedy was applied as an abortifacient (Sun et al. 1986).[10] Venereal disease undoubtedly brought on infertility, stillbirth, and miscarriage. A 1948 survey found a very low rate of pregnancy among a sample of five hundred prostitutes (Yü 1948:13).

The actual incidence of venereal disease among prostitutes is impossible to determine. A 1931 guidebook, its author intent on advertising the


273

pleasures of Shanghai's entertainment quarters, estimated that only 1 or 2 percent of all prostitutes were infected (T'ang 1931:154). But soon after the Japanese occupation, an investigative committee organized by women reformers under the auspices of the city government found that all of the pheasants rounded up in one relief effort (a total of thirty) had syphilis, and many suffered from gonorrhea as well (Ch'en Lu-wei 1938:21-22). A 1948 government report commented that most women contracted venereal disease within a year or two of beginning work as prostitutes. Of 1,420 working prostitutes examined by the municipal health authorities in 1946, 66 percent had venereal disease; the percentage was 62 percent for 3,550 women examined the following year. Most of these were cases of tertiary syphilis; the report noted that the numbers would have been still higher if a more reliable test for gonorrhea were included (Yü 1948:11, 13). Women who were examined and treated in government clinics represented only a tiny percentage of all prostitutes, most of whom had no contact with the medical system. Many who contracted syphilis were treated in the brothels with crude home remedies.

An examination of violence in the brothels makes clear the lack of control that prostitutes had over their working lives. Accounts of violence used by madams and brothel servants against prostitutes filled the Shanghai press during the Republican period. These reports usually concerned practices in lower-class brothels, where the madams beat their prostitutes for failing to bring customers home, for refusing to receive customers, for infractions of brothel rules, for stealing or being careless enough to let customers steal from them ("Demi-monde" 1923:786-87; SP April 8; May 29; June 10; July 6, 18; November 16, 1929:7; January 28, 1928:7). Some madams were sadistic as well as brutal; one put a cat inside the pants leg of a new prostitute who did not want to sleep with customers and whipped the cat until it lacerated the woman's leg (Ch'en Lu-wei 1938:22). When prostitutes fled to escape such abuse, they found scant refuge on the streets of Shanghai. The lucky ones were picked up by the police and remanded by the courts to the Door of Hope or another relief organization, with the ultimate expectation that they would find a spouse (sung-t'ang tse-p'ei ) (SP February 23; July 6, July 15, 1929:7). The others got no help from local patrolmen, who were often receiving regular payoffs from the madam. If a prostitute complained directly to police headquarters, the brothel owner might be fined a few dollars. But with no other way to make a living, a woman usually had to return to work as a prostitute (Ch'en Lu-wei 1938:22).

Very little is known about how the prostitutes regarded their work or themselves. Undoubtedly their outlook varied depending on whether the madam was cruel or kind, whether or not they had to entertain many guests, whether or not they became ill or pregnant. Certainly beautiful prostitutes in prestigious houses led a comfortable life compared with what they might


274

have expected in their families of origin. They ate well, dressed beautifully, and enjoyed the glamour surrounding their occupation. "Since seduction is her trade," commented a 1929 observer, "her dress sets her off from other women. Her rich apparel of brilliant silk makes her much better dressed than any class of women save the very rich. On the streets she is the object of attention for those who wish to see the new styles in feminine dress" (Wiley 1929:74). A 1920 newspaper article reported that upper-class prostitutes often wore jewels worth five or six thousand dollars (NCH June 26, 1920, cited in Wiley 1929:74). Of the five hundred prostitutes of all grades surveyed in 1948, 56 percent declared themselves satisfied with their occupation, mainly because it provided them with a relatively secure livelihood in a period of economic uncertainty. Less than a quarter were unhappy with their current circumstances (Yü 1948:12).

Nevertheless, social workers reported a variety of less sanguine attitudes on the part of prostitutes. Some, they found, articulated feelings of depression, inferiority, and suspicion (ibid., 12-13). Relief workers who interviewed such women reported that they were "as though anesthetized . . . numbed to the conditions of their existence." Unfortunately for the reformers, such emotional numbness did not translate into docility or willingness to reform. Given literacy training, the women in one program tore up their books and asked, "Why should we 'chew yellow beansprouts' here when in our 'own homes' servants will address us as 'Miss'?" In despair the social workers responsible for this program commented that "prostitutes are not ordinary women; they have deeply rooted vulgar practices, know no shame in their behavior, assume airs of importance, are lazy and full of ailments, like to sleep and cry, and are especially good at trickery" (Ch'en Lu-wei 1938:21-22). A former prostitute interviewed in the 1980s recalled the strategies women used to justify their existence to themselves:

You've got to have some idea in your head to keep you going. Otherwise you just couldn't take it, going with all those men. At first I just felt it was my fate and nothing could be done about it. Later I believed some of the things the other girls said. The craziest idea was it wasn't men having fun with us, but us having fun with them and they still had to pay good money. (Zhang and Sang 1987:33)

For these women, as for the prostitutes rounded up by the municipal government in the 1950s campaign to eradicate prostitution, it was no longer possible to imagine life outside the brothel system. Women dragged from the brothels in police raids during the 1950s often clung to their madams, weeping piteously and shouting, "Don't take me away from my 'mama'" (Ts'ao 1986). Though the madams might be oppressive and the effects of venereal disease debilitating, the fictive kinship networks of the brothels represented the only stable family many of these women knew, and they were loathe to leave it for an uncertain future.


275

Exit

When prostitutes imagined life outside the brothel system at all, they thought of becoming the wives or concubines of rich men. A quarter of the prostitutes surveyed in 1948 wanted to leave the life and marry a rich husband (Yu 1948:12) who was willing to pay off her "mortgage" or, if she had been sold outright, reimburse the madam for her purchase price plus interest and expenses. Some women, especially ones who were still young and attractive, left "the life" by this route (e.g., SP April 8, 1929:7), though such reports may have been exaggerated for their value in selling papers.[11]

For many women, an interim arrangement that might lead to a more permanent union was to be "rented" by a single patron. The man would pay a monthly fee to the madam and would either visit the woman regularly or take up residence in the brothel. Alternatively, he might install the woman in quarters of her own. Men who could not yet afford to redeem a prostitute's pawn pledge or buy her outright made use of this arrangement. In the late 1920s monthly rental fees could run as much as fifty yuan (Wei 1930:14; SP July 31, 1929:7).

In their search for a secure future, prostitutes used sexual strategies, particularly their capacity to bear children. Just as married women consolidated their positions in their husbands' families this way, so some prostitutes used pregnancy as a way out of prostitution and a ticket to marriage or at least concubinage. Ch'iao-nan, a young prostitute in Ta-ch'ing li, had a patron who was the scion of a wealthy family. Because she was beautiful, her madam treated her well and guarded her carefully and was reluctant to allow the young man to buy her out of the brothel. When Ch'iao-nan became pregnant, she and her lover agreed that she would not have an abortion. She refused the required doses of tadpoles, and when her pregnancy became so far advanced that there was no hope of her continuing to attract customers, the madam finally permitted her lover to purchase her (Sun et al. 1986). In cases like this, pregnancy was the occasion for struggles between prostitutes and owners over who controlled the disposition of sexual services and fertility decisions.

Women who were bought out of the brothels as concubines sometimes kept up contact with the madams who had raised them (Sun et al. 1986). Some reports indicate that women who had led active social lives as upper-class prostitutes found family life too sequestered and left their new husbands to seek a situation in which they enjoyed more autonomy (Lemière 1923:133). Others found that life as a concubine was in some respects less secure than life as a prostitute, depending as it did on the continuing favor of only one man. Women from lower-class brothels could seldom hope for a match with a rich man; some became wives of widowers and older men who could not afford a conventional match (Wiley 1929:76).

Many prostitutes did not cross over into marriage, but remained in the


276

sexual service business. If their looks declined before they had accumulated private money or connections, they became servants in the brothels. The more fortunate ones opened their own establishments and became madams. In Hui-le li, the only madams who actually resided in the lane were those who had just crossed over from prostitution into sexual service management. After making some money as madams, they moved elsewhere, returning to the lane only during working hours (Sun et al. 1986). Life as a madam afforded a woman a rare degree of autonomy. Although a madam, as noted earlier, needed to cultivate protection from men who might also threaten her, she was able to operate as a petty entrepreneur with the opportunity to amass considerable personal wealth.

The type of crossover strategy most frequently reported in the press, however, involved neither marriage nor becoming a madam, but flight. Women who could no longer tolerate the conditions of their employment, particularly in lower-class brothels, simply slipped out of the houses and sought refuge on the streets. One story reported in detail in the press involved a seventeen-year-old woman whose professional name was Red Cloud. Her madam was exceptionally cruel; Red Cloud was compelled to solicit customers on the street until four in the morning. If she failed to bring in business she was forced to kneel on broken tiles with a pan of water on her head, and was forbidden to sleep. Driven beyond endurance, Red Cloud fled the brothel early one morning and leaped into a rickshaw parked at the end of the lane. Upset to the point of incoherence, she could not tell the puller where to go, so she directed him by means of hand motions. After nine hours of running through almost every district in Shanghai, the hapless puller lost patience and asked her where she wanted to go. At this point she realized that she had no money to pay him, so she offered to marry him instead. Delighted, the puller told her that he might be too old for her (he was thirty-six), but that he had three younger brothers at home, all unmarried. He took her to his house in the Cha-pei district, whereupon his brothers immediately began to argue over who should have her as a wife. The tumult alerted some inquisitive neighbors, who suspected that the woman had been kidnapped and turned her and all the brothers in to the police (SP May 29, 1929:7).

It was not easy for prostitutes to free themselves from the control of the brothel system. Brothel owners employed both legal and illegal forms of coercion to keep women in their employ, particularly if the women had been mortgaged to them and the term had not yet expired. The power of such coercion can be seen in the case of Ma Jui-chen, a prostitute who briefly passed through a reform organization in the late 1930s. Ma was released from the reform school on court order and remanded to the custody of her mother. But as they left the courtroom, her mother told her that the madam had threatened the mother's life if she did not get the daughter released immediately. On the street they found the madam and several of her


277

"friends" (hsiang-hao ) waiting to escort them back to the brothel. The madam wanted to beat Ma and demanded immediate compensation for the two months' income she had lost while Ma was incarcerated. If Ma did not pay her immediately, she threatened to turn her over to the "boss" (lao-pan ), whom Ma referred to as "the highest penal official in the brothel," a man who might well kill her or sell her into another city. Then some of the madam's "friends" mediated. They convinced Ma and her mother to kneel in front of the madam and beg that Ma be allowed to continue to work in order to pay off the debt. Ma was sent back onto the street to solicit customers under the watchful eyes of the brothel servants.

For two days Ma deliberately failed to bring in customers. The madam cut off her food and threatened to have her hung up and beaten if she did not bring in some business before midnight. Ma fled to the local police station, which took her into protective custody. But when the police went to arrest the madam, they found that she had disappeared, warned by local detectives with whom she had a well-developed financial relationship. The police could only hold Ma in protective custody for twenty-four hours, and When they let her out one of the madam's "friends" took her to the madam, who had already seized her mother. Both mother and daughter were severely beaten. Only then did a bystander intervene and help Ma drag the madam and her accomplices to the police. But when the case went to court, the judge agreed that Ma and her mother were contractually bound to work for the madam; he ordered the mother to work as a maidservant in the brothel, while Ma was permitted to work outside as a maid. In this way she could pay off her debt while avoiding work as a prostitute. Only after the debt was cleared could she and her mother hope to return to the countryside district where Ma had grown up. State power thus intervened to legitimize and perpetuate the conditions of servitude in the brothels (Lu 1938:14-15).

Even when her pawn period was up, a prostitute often found it difficult to leave the brothel. Often she had nowhere to go. Moreover, madams, reluctant to lose a lucrative property, often tricked ignorant and illiterate women into agreeing to extensions on their contracts (SP April 8, 1929:7). When a woman did leave the brothel, it was invariably with financial help from a patron or someone else; in this arena women had little autonomy.

Only a woman who could prove that she had been forced into prostitution could hope to get legal help in fleeing the brothel system. Many cases that came before the courts in the Republican period thus centered around the contention, made by a prostitute or her relatives, that she had not voluntarily entered the brothel and they had not voluntarily sold her there. Madams routinely contested these assertions, saying that women had been sold to them as foster daughters or pawned as prostitutes. Because pawning or sale was a contractual transaction, madams frequently produced the signed contracts in court as proof that all parties had agreed to the arrangement.


278

Brothel owners who had acquired women by irregular means were not above forging such contracts or tricking women into signing them after the fact. The prostitutes, in turn, often contended that such documents had been signed under duress (SP April 8, 12; July 15; November 16, 1929:7).

The many efforts made by parents and other relatives of prostitutes to find and free them testify to the continuing ties between prostitutes and their kin, particularly in cases where the women had been kidnapped or tricked rather than sold. One peasant man brought a complaint against a madam after he came to Shanghai on business and saw his daughter soliciting customers at an amusement hall (SP June 10, 1929:7). Another peasant told the court that his younger brother's wife had been kidnapped and sold by her own relatives; the wife corroborated his testimony and asked to be released to his custody. Interestingly, the madam argued that the woman had been sold by her own father and that she could produce a contract to that effect, implying that this would make the sale legal and irrevocable (SP June 17, 1929:7). In a third case, a man from the rural hinterland of Shanghai discovered his fiancée working in a brothel four years after she had disappeared from their home county. He bought her from the madam (negotiating the asking price of a thousand yuan down to eight hundred) and married her (SP November 25, 1929:7).

But if a woman testified that she had become a prostitute of her own free will, then not even the protests of her relatives could free her. In a 1929 case, for instance, the mother of Sun Feng-ying petitioned the municipal court, saying her married daughter had been kidnapped and pawned into a French Concession brothel. But Sun herself testified that she had volunteered to become a prostitute to help pay the debts incurred by her husband's family when her sister-in-law became ill. The court dismissed the mother's corn-plaint (SP April 19, 1929:7). Conversely, a woman who did not wish to become a prostitute but was forced into it by relatives did have legal recourse. One woman retained a lawyer to petition the court to enjoin her mother from harassing her; the mother had forced her to engage in prostitution from age fourteen to twenty-nine (SP May 23, 1929:7). Both types of cases were exceedingly rare; usually the interests of the woman and her family were arrayed together against those of the brothel owners. In fact, it would appear that it was virtually impossible for a woman to leave the brothel system for a secure future unless she had either a rich patron or a loyal family (natal or marital) that was willing to testify for her in court.

Some prostitutes who grew old in the system without finding a rich patron or accumulating enough money to open their own establishment would adopt a daughter who could care for them in their old age or at least could yield a hefty brideprice when married off. However, for those prostitutes who had neither the means nor the foresight to invest in this arrangement, age brought a descent into less prestigious brothels, then into the ranks of


279

Shanghai beggars and itinerant entertainers (SP September 4, 1929:7; Wiley 1929:51-52).

Conclusion

How should we classify the market in prostitutes? In many ways, Shanghai prostitutes fit James Watson's definitions of slaves—they were acquired by purchase, their labor was secured by coercion (though the degree of actual physical force employed varied enormously), and they did not have, and could not attain, kinship status with their owners (1980a:8). They had a price on their heads, one that apparently correlated to market considerations of supply and demand as well as individual attributes of beauty, age, and virginity. Furthermore, they could be and often were resold. In short, it is tempting to regard these women as market commodities.

But portraying Shanghai prostitutes as slaves—that is, as fully detachable commodities that could be owned, bought, and sold—presents several problems. First, they were not fully detachable. Many prostitutes remained legally, emotionally, or financially attached to their natal or marital families. Using the language of slavery obscures the temporary nature of servitude for the majority of women who were pawned into prostitution. It also ignores the degree to which a fictive kinship structure was necessary in legitimating and maintaining the coercive relationship between madam and prostitute. Finally, the scattered evidence we have on struggles between prostitutes and their employers over claims on the woman's person indicates that both parties thought of the relationship as contractual rather than rooted in slave status and that the contracts were contestable in court. At a minimum, if these women were commodities, at least some of them put up an extraordinary struggle against such a status. To emphasize unduly the market transaction surrounding their entry into prostitution. directs attention precisely away from the complex and variegated. struggle of these women to assert some control over their working lives. It is more accurate, if less analytically tidy, to emphasize the ambiguity in their status, to say that they were treated as both persons and things by their families and by the madams who purchased long-term claims on them.

Conversely, if Shanghai prostitutes were not simply commodities themselves, neither had they "progressed" to the stage of selling their labor as a commodity for wages. Many of them received no regular wages, and even those who were in theory paid for their labor seldom saw or controlled the income. They were less than fully "free" to sell their labor to the highest bidder, or even to move from one workplace to another. Of course, in this lack of freedom they had much in common with other laborers; contract workers in the cotton mills and apprentices in small workshops had limited control over their own wages or mobility. Although less is known about


280

domestic servants, it seems probable that their employers regulated their living arrangements and leisure time in addition to their work. But the degree of control asserted over prostitutes by their employer/owners was extreme even by these standards. Prostitution in China involved more than wages for sex work; it included control by madams over a woman's fertility, sexual access, mobility, and life-style, as well as her labor. Rather than regarding the labor of prostitutes as fully commodified, it seems more accurate to say that what was being purchased were claims on a woman's attributes and services, rather than her actual labor, and that these claims were contestable in the courts and through flight from the brothel system.

The language of commodification causes another problem when applied to women up and down the hierarchy of Shanghai prostitution: it obscures status differences among the women themselves and imposes a false uniformity on their experience. The status of all prostitutes derived from the class background of their customers rather than their own family backgrounds. However derivative, a woman's status translated into real differences in daily working conditions, personal control over income, and possibilities for negotiating an advantageous exit from prostitution into concubinage or madamhood. The experience of a storytelling-house courtesan was radically different from that of a saltwater sister, and the two might well have had difficulty viewing themselves as members of a single profession. Noting the structural similarities of commodification should not blind us to the inequality among prostitutes, an inequality that mirrored the complex class structure of Shanghai society.

The language of commodification, then, cannot be applied neatly either to the women themselves or to their labor. Nevertheless, it must be said that in early twentieth-century Shanghai there was a growing market in which claims on women's bodies were exchanged: that is, that the commodification of women's bodies outside the marriage market was becoming more common. Perhaps the most important thing we can say about the Shanghai market in prostitutes is that it appears to have grown and changed during the first half of the twentieth century. During that period what had essentially been a luxury market in top-class courtesans became a market primarily geared to supplying sexual services for the growing numbers of unattached (though not necessarily unmarried) commercial and working-class men of the city. The increase in demand was apparently accompanied by a boom in supply, fed by a burgeoning population of refugees and peasants in distress with daughters they could not support. We cannot yet trace the fluctuating value of women on this larger market as brides, maidservants, concubines, or prostitutes. But it certainly looks as though the "popularization" of prostitution was accompanied by degenerating conditions of work for the individual prostitutes, or at least that more and more women participated in the less privileged and more vulnerable sectors of the trade. This trend, combined with the growth of various distinct reform cur-


281

rents among foreigners and Chinese in Shanghai, led to a series of loud, though largely ineffective, calls for the regulation or abolition of prostitution. Not until the early 1950s did the municipal government succeed in abolishing this particular market in women.

Glossary

chan-chieh chuaninline image

ch'ang-saninline image

chih-chiinline image

ch'u-chiinline image

chung-teng yi-shanginline image

erh-saninline image


283

Han-chu chia inline image

ho-ch'i chuaninline image

hsiang-haoinline image

hsiao hsien-shenginline image

hsien-jou chuanginline image

hsien-shui meiinline image

hsien-shenginline image

hua-yen chieninline image

k'ai-paoinline image

ko-tzu p'enginline image

lao-paninline image

lao-paoinline image

Lo-sung t'ang-tzuinline image

pao-changinline image

P'iao-ti men-chinginline image

shu-louinline image

shu-yuinline image

ssu-fang ch'ieninline image

sung-t'ang tse-p'eiinline image

t'ao-jeninline image

ting-p'enginline image

tu-chuehinline image

tzu-chi shen-t'iinline image

tzu-chia shen-t'iinline image

tso hua-t'ouinline image

ya-changinline image

yang-nüinline image

yao-erhinline image

yeh-chiinline image

yi-p'ao chu-yiinline image

References

Arlington, L. C. 1923. "The Chinese Female Names." China Journal of Science and Arts 1.4:316-25.

Champly, Henry. 1934. The Road to Shanghai: White Slave Traffic in Asia . Trans. Warre B. Wells. London: John Long.

Chang Hsin-hsin inline image and Sang Yeh inline image (see also Zhang Xinxin and Sang Ye). 1985. "Chiu-yü hsin-chih" inline image (Clients old and new). Tso-chia 1. Reprinted in Pei-ching jen 52. Shanghai, 1986.

Ch'en Jen-ping inline image. 1948. Yu-kuan Shang-hai erh-t'ung fu-li ti she-hui tiao-ch'ainline image (A social investigation concerning the welfare of Shanghai children). Shanghai: Shang-hai erh-t'ung fu-li tsu-chin hui.

Ch'en Lu-wei inline image. 1938. "Shou-jung chi-nü ti ching-kuo" inline image (The process of taking in prostitutes). Shang-hai fu-nü 1.1:21-22.

Chou, Eric. 1971. The Dragon and the Phoenix: Love, Sex, and the Chinese . London: Michael Joseph.

Courbin, Alain. 1986. "Commercial Sexuality in Nineteenth-Century France: A System of Images and Regulations." Representations 14 (Spring): 209-19.

Crad, Joseph. 1940. Traders in Women: A Comprehensive Survey of "White Slavery. " London: John Long.

De Leeuw, Hendrik. 1933. Cities of Sin . New York: Harrison Smith & Robert Haas.

Delacoste, Frederique, and Priscilla Alexander, eds. 1987. Sex Work: Writings by Women in the Sex Industry . Pittsburgh: Cleis Press.

"The Demi-monde of Shanghai." 1923. China Medical Journal 37:782-88.

Gronewold, Sue. 1982. Beautiful Merchandise: Prostitution in China 1860-1936 . New York: Institute for Research in History and the Haworth Press.

Hauser, Ernest O. 1940. Shanghai: City for Sale . New York: Harcourt, Brace.

Henderson, Edward. 1871. A Report on Prostitution in Shanghai . Shanghai: North-China Herald Office.


284

Hinder, Eleanor M. 1942. Social and Industrial Problems of Shanghai . New York: Institute of Pacific Relations·

Honig, Emily. 1986. Sisters and Strangers: Women in the Shanghai Cotton Mills, 1919-1949 . Stanford: Stanford University Press·

———. 1987. "The Making of an Underclass: Subei People in Shanghai·" Paper prepared for the Social Science Research Council Conference on Economics and Chinese History, Oracle, Arizona, January 1988.

Lemière, J. Em. 1923. "The Sing-song Girl: From a Throne of Glory to a Seat of Ignominy·" China Journal of Science and Arts 1.2:126-34·

Liu P'ei-ch'ien inline image. 1936. Ta Shang-hai chih-naninline image (A guide to greater Shanghai). Shanghai: Chung-hua shu-chü.

Lo Chih-ju inline image. 1932. T'ung-chi piao chung chih Shang-haiinline image (Shanghai in statistical charts). Nanking: Kuo-li chung-yang yen-chiu yuan.

Lo Ch'iung inline image. 1935. "Ch'ang-chi tsai Chung-kuo" inline image (Prostitution in China). Fu-nü sheng-huo 1.6:34-40.

Lu Wei inline image. [Chen Lu-wei inline image]. 1938. "T'iao-ch'u huo-k'eng yi-hou: chi-nü Ma Jui-chen tzu-shu" inline image (After jumping out of the fiery pit: an account in her own words by prostitute Ma Jui-chen). Shang-hai fu-nü 1.12:14-15.

McCartney, J. L. 1927. "Chinese Military Medicine·" U.S. Naval Medical Bulletin (October).

Mann, Susan. 1988. "Pariah Communities in Qing Society." Paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the Association for Asian Studies, San Francisco·

———. 1983. "What Can Feminist Theory Do for the Study of Chinese History?" Paper presented at the California Regional Seminar in Chinese Studies, Berkeley·

Miers, Suzanne, and Igor Kopytoff, eds. 1977. Slavery in Africa: Historical and Anthropological Perspectives . Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Morris, M. C. 1916. "Chinese Daughters of the Night." Missionary Review (October).

NCH. North-China Herald . Shanghai.

O'Callaghan, Sean. 1968. The Yellow Slave Trade: A Survey of the Traffic in Women and Children in the East . London: Anthony Blond·

Pan Ling. 1983. In Search of Old Shanghai . Hong Kong: Joint Publishing Co.

Robertson, Claire C., and Martin A. Klein, eds. 1983. Women and Slavery in Africa . Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Rubin, Gayle. 1975. "The Traffic in Women: Notes on the 'Political Economy' of Sex." In Toward an Anthropology of Women , ed. Rayna Reiter. New York and London: Monthly Review Press.

Shanghai Bureau of Social Affairs. 1929. Wages and Hours of Labor, Greater Shanghai, 1929 . Shanghai.

SCA. Shanghai Civic Association/Shang-hai shih ti-fang hsieh-hui pien-chi inline image. 1933. Shanghai Statistics/Shang-hai shih t'ung-chiinline image. Shanghai.

SSWH. Shang-hai shih wen-hsien wei-yuan-hui inline image. 1948. Shang-hai jen-k'ou chih-luehinline image (Brief record of the Shanghai population).

SP. Shih-paoinline image. Shanghai·

SVC. Special Vice Committee. March 19, 1920. "Vice Conditions in Shanghai." Municipal Gazette 13.681:83-86.


285

Sun Li-ch'i, Yu Hui-ch'ing, Yuan Hsiang-mei, Chang P'ei-hua, and Ts'ao Chu-hsien (former residents of Shanghai's brothel districts). 1986. Group interview with author. Shanghai, November 15.

T'ang Yu-feng inline image. 1931. Hsin Shang-haiinline image (New Shanghai). Shanghai: Shang-hai yin-shu-kuan.

Tien, H. Yuan. 1973. China's Population Struggle . Columbus: Ohio State University Press.

Ts'ao Man-chih. 1986. Interview with author. Shanghai, November 10.

T'u Shih-p'in inline image, ed. 1948; reprint, 1968. Shang-hai ch'un-ch'iuinline image (Shanghai annals). Hong Kong: Chung-kuo t'u-shu pien-yi-kuan.

Wang Chung-